Finanzen

A Different Solution For The Greek Tragedy

Lesezeit: 88 min
08.07.2015 23:05
Greek economic statistics are seriously distorted, for conceptual and political reasons. Greece is a country with a very large and highly competitive export industry. Its merchant fleet has been the world’s largest since the 1970s. Its tourism sector enjoys a very strong position in Europe. An extremely deflationary foreign trade price shock is aggravated by a misguided policy of internal deflation, which leads to a debt-deflation spiral. The solution of the Greek crisis needs to be different from the traditional approach of the Troika.
A Different Solution For The Greek Tragedy
Representative freight rates of Greece’s shipping companies, annual average. (Grafik: Bloomberg, OPEC)

Mehr zum Thema:  
Europa >
Benachrichtigung über neue Artikel:  
Europa  

Introduction

This article contains a counter-consensus analysis of Greece’s economic crisis. This crisis appears to be following the script of an ancient Greek tragedy. The tragedy is leading deeper and deeper into a conflict which is irresolvable for the persons involved and which will end in a collapse or catastrophe. There is no way to avoid blame without denying their inner values and losing their public standing. The climax of the crisis was reached with the collapse of talks between institutions and the Greek government and the mother of all banking crisis after June 27th. This article was originally written in April and May 2015 and published in German in early June 2015. The article is left unchanged except for addendums to cover the events of June 27th / 28th and complete the analysis.

This article is the non-technical summary of a larger text. The main statements of the article are substantiated in detail in this background text. Several informative graphs and tables are attached in an annex out of which only a few will be shown illustratively for reasons of space. The article’s essential arguments are briefly summarised as follows:

Brief Summary

The Troika’s policy towards Greece is based on a fatal statistical error

Ostensibly, the crisis in Greece is about sovereign debt. It apparently resulted from an overly expansionary fiscal policy and a loss of price competitiveness since the launch of the euro. This competitive weakness is supposedly attributable to an excessive rise in labour costs with respect to anaemic macroeconomic productivity growth. Greece is allegedly uncompetitive internationally because the economy’s internal structures do not allow for or support any internationally competitive industries. Bureaucracy, poor regulation, especially in the labour market, excessively high wages and costs are said to be structurally obstacles. Apparently, these are the causes of the periodic disruptions which, in ever shorter intervals, have pushed the country to the edge of bankruptcy since 2010. Hence, also, the strict austerity and deflation program which the Troika has imposed on the country since 2010.

The core problem is actually completely different: Greece is a country with a very large and highly competitive export industry. Its merchant fleet has been the world’s largest since the 1970s. Greek merchant shipping made huge efficienciy gains since the turn of the century. Its tourism sector enjoys a very strong position in Europe. In the 2000s, it successfully evolved from mass to quality tourism, with very competitive prices in the upper and particularly in the top price segments. The country experienced an export boom from 1999 to 2008. No other western European country except for Norway achieved even remotely comparable export growth. Due to conceptual errors in the calculation of the balance of payments and gross domestic product, this export boom was recorded as a growing current account deficit and sluggish GDP growth. Actually, up till 2008, Greece achieved high and steeply increasing current account surpluses, more than Germany did. This export boom was mainly driven by merchant shipping, the country’s dominant economic sector since the 1960s.

Greek economic statistics are seriously distorted, for conceptual and political reasons. This is shown in the background text for the two main export industries, merchant shipping and tourism.

Balance of payment statistics for both industries are collected by the Bank of Greece. Merchant shipping specifically has been conceptually misrepresented in Greece’s balance of payments since it returned to Greece in the 1960s and therefore for more than 50 years. Greece differs in this respect from all other important countries with a merchant fleet. This has to do with its currency exposure and the regulation and taxation of the sector in Greece as well as with the country’s monetary policy regime up till 1994. Since the 1980s, this problem has been known worldwide as the “missing fleet” phenomenon, which even considerably distorts current account balances worldwide and not only Greece’s. Unlike in the rest of the world, up to 1998 in Greece, shipping companies’ freight earnings from abroad were not reported as merchant shipping exports. These exports comprised only transfers to Greece from shipowners’ dollar accounts held abroad. These so-called remittances only covered only domestic factor costs – seamen’s wages, salary payments including the state NAT pension fund in Greece, domestic inputs and company earnings and dividends paid in Greece. All merchant shipping earnings are denominated in USD (formerly also in GBP), because this is how freight rates are posted worldwide. They were held exclusively in the shipowners’ dollar accounts abroad, because Greece had a capital controls regime from 1932 to 1994 inclusive which did not permit any international capital transactions. Shipowners effected the really large payments for their merchant fleets such as the purchase of ships, amortization and interest payments on shipping loans, purchase of fuel, operating expenses such as port and canal fees and labour costs for non-Greeks exclusively from their dollar accounts held abroad. The statistical coverage of merchant shipping in Greece by the central bank improved superficially when it entered the euro. The payments received by Greek banks are fully recorded by a reporting system known as the International Transaction Reporting System (ITRS) introduced newly in 1999, which was previously not the case. Also, a part of overseas freight earnings started being effectively recorded in accounts in Greece. This was a condition made by Greece-domiciled banks for the substantial loans granted to shipowners, especially from 2005/06. The percentage of merchant shipping export earnings included in the Greek balance of payments thereby rose from about 10% in 1999 to about 25% in 2008. However, most of the sector’s exports, about three-quarters to four-fifths depending on the calculation method, are still not recorded statistically in the balance of payments and the national accounts. Due to a constellation of power in domestic politics, the Greek central bank acts reluctantly and defensively. The dominant freight earnings in the dollar accounts abroad are still unrecorded as before. These were mainly the ships of Greek shipowners flying flags of convenience. Conceptually, according to the 1977, 1993 and 2008 (BPM 4/5/6) IMF balance of payments manuals, they are obviously to be assigned to the operating centre’s freight earnings and this is Piraeus or Athens. Similar collection problems also apply to a lesser extent in tourism. The collection procedure there was converted to a new system – the Frontier Travel System (FTS) – with the introduction of the euro. Due to serious errors in tourism sector statistics, this is unable to capture qualitative changes such as the spectacular expansion of five-star hotels in the 2000s. As a result, average hotel prices and per diem tourist spending is distortedly recorded. Consequently, tourism sector exports are also viewed in absolute terms and inaccurately reflected in the temporal dynamic.

Greece’s export industry is very competitive and is oriented towards the world economy’s above-average growth sectors and is therefore well positioned. However, it is insufficiently diversified and is particularly concentrated on an extremely cyclical major sector – merchant shipping. Furthermore, in comparison to the rest of the world, the Greek fleet is concentrated on the segments of merchant shipping which are the most cyclical by far, namely, tankers and dry bulk carriers - transport ships for raw materials such as iron ore, coal, grain etc. Since 2008, both these segments have been exposed to an extreme sectoral price decline which is hitting all operators hard. The same sequence as that of the 1970s and early 80s is being repeated: Strong synchronised growth in the world economy, full capacity utilisation, a steep rise in freight rates, large orders for very big ships (early 1970s, second half of the 2000s), then the first oil shock (1973; 2007/08), then the second oil shock (1979/80; 2011-14), sharp fall in demand for sea freight and high overcapacity combined with a collapse in freight rates. In 2014/15, the average freight rates for tankers were about 30 – 40% below the average for the 2000s. For dry bulk carriers freight rates have even declined by 70 -80%. In contrast to the 2008 peak level, the falls were even as high as 50% and 95% respectively. In the hotel and restaurant sector, prices also fell by about 20% compared to 2007/08. The collapse of Greece’s exports is a cyclical sectorally-determined slump. No other country suffered such a collapse of exports as a result of concentration risks. Nevertheless, during the expansion phase and also during the recession since 2008, Greece clearly strengthened its competitive position in these two export industries in comparison to the rest of the world. However, Greece has been much weakened as an economy.

An extremely deflationary foreign trade price shock...

What first brought Greece to its knees was an extremely deflationary foreign trade price shock. The two oil shocks of 2007/08 and 2011- 14 represent enormous burdens not only for its merchant fleet, but for the Greek economy as a whole. In the 1990s, Greece spent about 1% of its nominal GDP on its visible oil bill (net energy imports minus energy exports) annually. In the years 2006 – 14, this percentage increased to an average of over 4% of the nominal EDP – GDP. This percentage even exceeded 5% during the peak years. In addition, there are fuel costs for the merchant fleet which is refuelled around worldwide and hardly ever in Greece. That expenditure is not included in the Greek trade balance. It should be recorded under imports (intermediate inputs) of shipping services. If all the freight earnings of Greek shipping companies was correctly recorded and not only about one – quarter, the energy bill would actually increase to about 15 – 20% of the correctly calculated nominal GDP.

No other developed economy is as massively dependent on oil prices as Greece is. This dependency reflects the country’s maritime exposure. Greece has thousands of islands, many of which are tourist destinations that are very remote from the mainland and must be reached by sea or by air, which entails high transport costs. On the islands, electricity and heating are provided only by oil/gas combustion in thermal power plants. Greece also has the world’s largest merchant fleet. The fleet’s fuel expenditure represents the greater part of the costs of voyages and – during oil shocks such as since 2001 – even the total cost. What hit Greece massively, unlike any other economy, is a double price shock in its foreign trade. A collapse in its key export prices since 2008 and, parallel to that, a price explosion in import or input prices. Hence the extreme deflationary pressure from the foreign trade sector. The Greek central bank’s official current account figures therefore present a false picture because they only record a fraction of freight earnings and energy expenditure: exports could have been underestimated by about 60 billion euro for 2008. Correctly calculated, the current account was in surplus from 1999 to 2007/08 and there has been a big deficit since then. The official current account balance shows exactly the opposite of the actual development, with disastrous consequences for the interpretation of the economic problems and the formulation of a policy response.

In essence, at issue is a cyclical international trade price shock, identical to that of the early 1980s. It first started in 2008, after the terms of trade in international trade had previously been extremely favourable to Greece’s current account. It’s the exact same constellation as in the early 80s: a fall in freight rates combined with the second oil shock of 1979/80, which then lasted till 1985. It’s a classical terms of trade shock which is unrelated to the internal price and costs dynamics in Greece. Greece is a pure price-taker for these goods and services. In the 1980s, Greece’s policy responded correctly in principle, namely, with an expansionary fiscal policy. In the 1980s, this prevented a slide into a severe recession or depression. Two things were wrong at that time:

- Labour market policy and wage determination in the core sector, merchant shipping. Steeply rising salaries for Greek seamen as a result of the wrong choice of reference currency for the payment of wages after 1977, led to a dramatic loss of seafaring jobs in Greece in the first half of the 1980s. This had grave consequences for shipowners’ remittances and the current account at the time and favoured a fall in the Greek drachma.

- The fiscal expansion was not implemented as a temporary economic policy measure. It was continued unchanged under different economic conditions and paved the way for clientelist party politics with the well-known consequences for budget deficits and government debt.

The state of official data and the prevailing analysis of the growing current account deficits since the introduction of the euro are incorrect. Correctly calculated, Greece never showed deficits between 1999 and 2008, but rather increasing surpluses. Just as wrong is the claim of insufficient productivity gains and even more so, that of excessive labour costs increases. Solely as a result of the recording of a fraction of merchant shipping earnings, the GDP for the years 2007 and 2008 was underestimated by about 15 to 20%. On the contrary, from 2003 to 2008, wages increased insufficiently with respect to the productivity gains actually achieved. When correctly measured, real wages were already in decline during the upswing, although the economy was experiencing the biggest boom in Western Europe. Furthermore, budget deficits and the level of government debt relative to actual GDP were nothing like the order of magnitude in the EDP procedure. The only thing that is correct is that the balance of payments data published by the Greek central bank and the national account data derived therefrom support the interpretation of rising wage costs and an overly expansionary fiscal policy superficially, from a highly aggregated perspective.

…is aggravated by a misguided policy of internal deflation …

Hence, the Troika formulated a wrong response, i.e. an unprecedented internal deflation as a response to an external deflation of a rare extent in a small open economy. The concept of internal devaluation, as it is called, is inappropriate for several reasons:

- Greece’s export economy does not benefit at all from very low wages and prices. This has to do with its structure. Earnings and expenditure by merchant shipping, the largest export industry by far, are almost exclusively dollar-denominated and have little or nothing to do with Greek labour costs. In contrast to the situation at the beginning of the 1980s, shipping companies now employ fewer Greek seamen. Most seamen are Filipinos and Indians, who are paid in their home currencies. In addition, the merchant fleet is extremely capital intensive, and this is in contrast to its structure some decades ago. Many of the exporters in the tourism sector are family businesses with low numbers of non-family employees. By contrast, the bigger firms operating five-star and four-star hotels are capital intensive. So, on the contrary, wages did not constitute a hindrance to the unprecedented expansion in five-star hotels since 2003. In any case, in both industries, cheap, unreported work of illegal immigrants is a significant form of employment.

- The internal devaluation policy does not take into consideration the previous strong credit expansion and debt levels of private households and companies. Nominal incomes were reduced through seriously reduced wages, pensions and prices as well as through high unemployment. As the outstanding debt to the banking sector and to the state remains unchanged, the current burden of interests, amortisation and taxes and the value of the outstanding debt continue to rise in real terms. A debt deflation situation has been thus created.

- This debt deflation was greatly aggravated by the systemic banking crisis which acts as a financial accelerator for the economic crisis. A withdrawal of foreign interbank deposits started with the supposed 2010 sovereign debt crisis, which led to a lending freeze in the banking system. The Troika unwittingly intensified this process. Monetary policy was ultra-restrictive because the banking system’s equity capital was temporarily destroyed by the debt cut imposed by the Troika in 2011. It has never been adequate built up again since then. Due to this credit event, the banks were obliged to immediately make extremely high write-offs. This destroyed a large part of their capital. However, recapitalization did take place, but belatedly, in 2012 and 2013. The banks had to suspend or strongly curb lending because of the temporary massive reduction in their capital. The lending freeze led to the collapse of construction investment to almost zero. The liquidity crisis stemming from the banking crisis spread to large sections of the real economy and pushed tens of thousands of companies and households into bankruptcy and cost hundreds of thousands of employees their income. The banks’ non-performing and bad loans rose steeply as a consequence of the general liquidity crisis. These bad loans have to be backed by much higher equity with the result that even after the belated recapitalisation, the banks themselves were unable to come out of the situation of inadequate equity or risk capital. The massively deflationary policy exercised through the banking system together with the foreign trade price shock (fall in export prices combined with skyrocketing oil prices) lies at the heart of the Greek crisis. The temporary destruction of banks’ equity capital triggered a systemic banking crisis which is reflected in an almost unprecedent credit crunch and a liquidity crisis extending over the whole economy.

- The role of fiscal policy alone in the crisis is overestimated or incorrectly assessed. A consolidation was necessary, granted. But the Troika set the priorities badly. The fiscal consolidation was not only too abrupt; it had extremely negative distorting effects from an economic policy standpoint. Those who had been paying taxes up to then – workers in regular employment and households – now pay much more and receive lower benefits. The combination of tax measures – especially the sharply increased rates of VAT, income tax and profit tax – and spending cuts has greatly increased the incentives for tax evasion in the commercial sector. Consequently, those who had been paying little or no tax up till then still pay none or too little. Certainly, many of the self-employed and many companies can no longer pay because of the economic situation. In contrast, it would have been relatively easy to get hold of considerable amounts of evaded taxes parked in offshore accounts abroad, without such economic damage.

… which leads to a debt-deflation spiral

This is why this article characterizes the crisis as a debt-deflation spiral. Because the policy of internal devaluation adds an internal debt deflation to the external debt deflation in the economy’s most important sector, merchant shipping, and triggers a comprehensive and cumulatively intensifying process of macroeconomic debt deflation. The four characteristic elements are the destruction of banking system equity or risk capital, falling real estate and ship prices, which are the most important collateral for bank loans, steeply rising bad loans and periodic withdrawal panics among banking system depositors. The banks can no longer make loans and plunge the economy into a comprehensive liquidity crisis. The banking crisis acts as a financial accelerator of a cumulatively intensifying economic collapse. Debt deflation consists of sharply falling nominal incomes and prices together with unchanged nominal debt owed to the banks and rapidly rising nominal debt to the government. Interest rates and the tax burden rise drastically in real terms due to the fall in nominal income making debts and borrowing costs unsustainable. The manifest sovereign debt crisis reflects only one underlying process of a full-fledged debt deflation.

Given this analysis, the major policy options will be discussed at the end of this article and both an exit from the euro and a continuation of internal devaluation have been rejected. An exit from the euro would damage shipping and tourism irreversibly. A devaluation would not benefit sea transport, because its costs and revenues are dollar – denominated. Moreover, these two major export industries are very capital intensive. The four- and five-star hotel segments of the tourism sector offer potential which requires high capital expenditure, just like sea transport. The potential of both sectors of the economy can only be fulfilled by remaining in the euro with a banking system that can provide an elastic credit supply at low interest rates. A return to the drachma would mean high and volatile interest rates with fluctuating risk premiums.

The focus of attention is not on “reform” measures of the existing type, but neither on selective social or fiscal policy measures. The Troika’s “reforms” only deepened the domestic economy’s debt deflation. Given the unprecedented banking crisis, the banking system must be immediately recapitalized and the credit mechanism restored. This is the only way to alleviate the country’s catastrophically acute liquidity crisis. A further financing of the public budget alone will not suffice and, if accompanied by further falls in wages and pensions or VAT increases, will only aggravate debt deflation. The most important points concern a rapid and substantial recapitalization of the banks, a transfer of non-performing and bad loans to a properly designed “bad bank”, the abolition of withholding tax on interest income on domestic bank deposits and a profound modification of merchant shipping regulation. Shipowners must disclose all their accounts, including offshore accounts to both tax authorities and the central bank. They must report global turnover and inputs annually and on a reduced scale on a quarterly base. Shipowners should be allowed to retain their tax privileges for shipping activities within the existing framework. But besides transparency only if they hold their liquidity in Greece instead of in offshore accounts abroad. This is the only way the banking system deposit base can be rebuilt. These measures will cost something initially, but can be revisited during a subsequent privatisation.

Initial Situation: The Missing Fleet

The standard analysis has it that Greece, like the other periphery countries, lost some of its competitiveness when it adopted the euro. Price competitiveness suffered due to excessively high wage rises in relation to weak productivity gains. This was supposedly made possible by an expansionary spending policy. In a currency union, this wage-dependent competitive disadvantage can only be corrected through drastic nominal and real wage reductions. Drastic structural budget cuts must be made in order to achieve a primary surplus. Hence the policy of wage cuts and reductions in nominal wages in both the public and private sectors which were carried out relentlessly. Hence the endless hikes in direct and especially indirect taxes and levies. Hence the spending cuts in investments, current spending and pensions. In this view, an economic collapse is an unavoidable adjustment effect of this austerity and deflationary policy. The weak export performance can only be improved by microeconomic structural reforms to the labour market, the deregulation of the whole economy and comprehensive reform of the state. By contrast, competitive disadvantages can be compensated for in the event of an exit from the euro by the associated devaluation. Proponents of this interpretation such as Hans-Werner Sinn recommend that leaving the currency union would serve the country best.

What can excuse this interpretation and this action approach are Greece’s official economic statistics. With respect to the calculation of the balance of payments, external position and gross domestic product, especially exports, but also imports and investment in building construction, they are incorrect. They have actually been depicting a desolate picture of the Greek economy with respect to export growth for a long time, and especially since the launch of the euro. The Greek central bank is primarily responsible for this. It has been organising the balance of payment statistics for decades. The government statistics office only takes over these results and fits them into the national accounts. Hence, the fact that the reactions in economic policy in Europe and Germany to the euro crisis which started from Greece were of this nature is explainable and can be accepted. However, the Troika’s experts and policy advisers called in by the German and European decision-makers were also incompetent, and not only the Bank of Greece. In the event of a crisis, the one of the first things to do is always to examine the quantitative figures and to trace every possible weak point. And a critical examination would have thrown out the whole representation. Nevertheless, let us state the facts:

Greece’s exports have been structurally underestimated in the service balance for decades, because only a small part of merchant shipping or the shipping companies was included, and indeed a part decreasing over a period of time up to 1998. This sector has been dollar-denominated since the 1950s and especially on the revenues side and – increasingly – on the expenditure side. This is why Greek shipowners traditionally hold accounts with banks in New York, London and Geneva and have historically almost never made payments through Greek or Greece-domiciled banks until the introduction of the euro. The fact that shortly after the establishment of the Bank of Greece (in 1929), Greece went over to a regime with rigid capital controls in 1932 and maintained this regime more or less unaltered until 1994 also played a role in this respect. It was almost impossible to carry out international capital transactions through Greek banks. In view of this monetary policy regime, the central bank dispensed with recording the freight revenues of shipowners operating in Greece and to designate them as exports. This was in contrast to the practice of almost all other countries with an influential merchant fleet. The only things that were recorded on the income side of the shipping sector’s balance sheet up to and including 1998 were the shipping companies’ internal factor costs – wages and social security contributions, especially payments into the seamen’s NAT pension funds, domestic intermediate inputs and dividends and company revenues paid out in Greece. They were financed by means of shipowners’ transfers (remittances) from their dollar accounts held abroad. The freight revenues of Greek shipping companies were historically almost never recorded in either Greece’s nor in foreign countries balance of payments up till 1998. That is the problem of the “missing fleet” which has occupied the international balance of payments statistics since the early 1980s. The greater part of freight revenues and liquidity remained in dollar accounts abroad. This liquidity came into domestic circulation in Greece though through various channels, but in highly cyclical manner. Structurally, up to and including 2002, the reinvested proceeds do not remain in the foreign accounts at all, and have been insufficiently recorded since 2003. Because the shipping companies possess large and increasing capital abroad, their revenues were completely mixed therewith. By the time it adopted the euro, Greece’s current account, if correctly calculated, was in surplus and not in deficit, as represented in the official figures. By the end of the 1990s, with respect to export proceeds, the shipping companies were actually several times more important than tourism and even more so than the export of goods.

The unrecorded export proceeds of Greek shipping companies have been an issue in international economic statistics for decades. Thus, after several attempts, American authorities and the IMF discovered that the evidently incorrect figures of the American and global current accounts balances were largely attributable to the inadequate recording of the freight revenues of Greek shipowners. Between 1984 and 1987, the IMF carried out a comprehensive investigation into the reasons for the negative global current account balances through a working group (Esteva Report). In principle, the surpluses and deficits of the current accounts of all countries should balance out. However, from the 1970s, a rapidly increasing tendency towards aggregated deficits of about 100 billion USD was established between 1981 and 1985. One of the three fundamental reasons identified, actually the most significant, was the non-reporting of income from the shipping industry by a few countries with very large fleets, Greece and Hong Kong being at the forefront (“The Missing Fleet”).2 In subsequent years, the considerable discrepancy between reported credits and debits in sea freight transport was also an issue for working groups from time to time.3 In the 2000s the discrepancies in the sea transport balance virtually exploded, without any further clarifications. In the past, concealed trends of “invisibles” in the balance of payments were responsible for many macroeconomic enigmas and policy errors. The fact that the shipping companies’ surpluses must have caused very serious distortions not only for the U.S. balance of payments, but also for the current account balances of the much smaller Greece was never identified as a central issue in the IMF documents. This reflects a form of organisational blindness.

Greece’s fleet of tankers and bulk carriers has been the world’s largest since the 1970s. The tankers carry crude oil and products such as petrol, diesel and kerosene, chemicals or also gas. The so-called dry bulk carriers transport bulk cargo goods such as iron ore, coal, grain, bauxite or phosphate. This is a growth sector of the world economy, with growth rates clearly above

The International Monetary Fund: Final Report of the Working Party on the Statistical Discrepancies in World Current Account Balances, Washington D.C. (1987) came to the following sobering conclusion with respect to Greece’s shipowners: “Moreover, the Greek balance of payments excludes the operations of the Greek fleet because the owners of that fleet do not reside in Greece and, as far as the IMF is aware, they are not residents in other countries either”. (IMF, 1987, p. 90).

IMF: Global Discrepancies in the Transportation Account. Fifteenth Meeting of the IMF Committee on Balance of Payments Statistics, Canberra, Australia, October 21 – 25, 2002. those of the world’s aggregate output or even more so, than the gross national product of the OECD countries. In the 2000s, merchant shipping and particularly the two largest segments occupied by Greek shipowners profited from a boom similar to that of the 1970s due to emerging economies’ hunger for raw materials. Freight rates, i.e. the prices for transport services, in both these areas precisely – for tankers and bulk cargo carriers – rose several-fold within a few years just like crude oil prices. Freight rates for bulk cargo increased seven-fold between 1999 and 2007/08 in dollars, if measured in annual averages. In euro terms, they quintupled. Freight rates for tankers increased six-fold between 1995 and 2008 in both dollar and euro terms.

Added to this are large economies of scale due to the fleet’s build-up, maximum capacity utilisation and efficiency gains in the boom years. Measured in ton-miles, transport capacity supposedly grew by more than 50% from the end of the 1990s to 2008 and doubled by 2014. All this is not reflected in the Greek current account. Since 1999, only transfers paid to the shipowners Greek branch through Greek or Greece-domiciled banks have been recorded therein as shipping company exports. This is a only a part which mainly covers the ships which were purchased new in the 2000s and paid through transaction in Greece-domiciled banks. The banks usually require that payments for a foreign-financed ship be made through accounts held directly with them to guarantee loans. Additionally, there are revenues from management agreements of the management company with the offshore companies owning the vessels. Furthermore, the Bank of Greece uses publicely available information from listed shipping companies. However, the majority of revenues for foreign financed ships and from ships mostly under foreign flags that are paide off are not captured. Using six different statistical procedures and approximations, the annex shows that only about 15 % of the exports of the Greek merchant fleet were recorded in 1999 and only about a fifth in 2008.

As an illustration of how absurd the figures in the Greek current account are, the load capacity of the large European merchant fleets will be compared with the nominal production values for the shipping industry according to the National Account System (NAS). The latter are, as far as Greece or even Denmark are concerned, identical to the current account export values except for minor differences. Both countries have a cross-trader fleet. They transport goods mainly or exclusively between third countries. In Greece’s case, the production values are derived directly from the balance of payments values. In contrast, the fleets of bigger countries such as Germany or the U.K. also supply the domestic economy. This is why part of the output is recorded as services for the domestic economy and not as an export. Hence the comparison of carrying capacity measured in dead weight tonnage with production values and not just export values. The carrying capacity is taken from the statistics of the international trade organisation UNCTAD in its annually published “Review of Maritime Transport”. This is the standard publication for worldwide merchant shipping. During the 2000s, fleets were almost continuously fully occupied, in contrast to the 1980s and 1990s. Production values are defined according to identical criteria on the basis of the ESA 95 standards of the national accounts system.

The first diagram shows that the fleet controlled from Greece displays quite a different dimension from all other fleets. It’s only since 2008 that the German fleet has had an order of magnitude equivalent to about half of the Greek fleet. In the late 2000s, Germany experienced an strong growth in capacity in the container fleet. At that time, the dimensions of the fleets of all other countries were smaller than the one controlled from Greece. The picture would be different if the production values were used in accordance with the NAS. According to the second graph, in the 2000s, Greece supposedly produced not only much less output than Germany and Denmark. It was also mediocre in comparison to countries with much smaller fleets like the UK or Norway. The carrying capacity of the United Kingdom’s fleet never amounted to more than 10% of that of Greece. Even countries with an almost insignificant fleet like France or Italy have almost the same order of magnitude with regard to the gross production value as the world’s largest fleet by far.

 

Some observations should be made here.

- The collection procedure for other countries’ fleets is fundamentally different from that of Greece. In the other countries, the shipowners’ industry associations carry out in-depth surveys of their members at least yearly, sometimes quarterly and publish them shortly after. This occurs in Germany, the United Kingdom, Denmark, Norway and France. In these countries, shipowners are required to disclose their turnover and other figures to government authorities. By contrast, in Greece, neither the central bank nor any other authorities have access to the company data. Due to the Greek form of tonnage tax, shipping companies are not required to file tax returns. The Greek central bank relies on the ITRS and makes adjustments. The error in Greece’s conceptual approach is that the national ITRS is not linked internationally. As the shipowners’ foreign accounts are omitted, this causes these enormous distortions. The Greek approach would resemble a multinational company, that calculates their global turnover or sales from inflows in the headquarter treasury.

- During the period from 2000 to 2011, depending on the year Greece had 40 – 50% of the carrying capacity of the whole of Europe’s fleet, not only of the countries listed in the graph. Therefore, turnover should – with a large standard deviation – be about as large as the sum of all the turnover of the countries listed in the illustration together. Actually, it should even be far larger up to 2008, because Greece was specialised in the areas in which freight rates skyrocketed. That would be about 100 billion euro for 2008. If the shipowners who are indeed recorded as Greek but who were operating abroad are also counted, then a turnover of about 80 billion euro would be obtained. There is a discrepancy of roughly 60 bn euro with the recorded size of 20 billion euro or a quarter of nominal GDP. Note that this is a rough estimate. However it is confirmed by comparison with five other indicators in the approximate order of magnitude in the annex. Conversely, the 2011 collapse must have been much larger, because freight rates had already fallen sharply by this time.

In Greece, shipping companies have been exempt from taxes on profits, capital levy and capital gains since a 1957 tax reform and this exemption has even been constitutionally mandated since 1975. In addition, shipowners as private individuals are exempt from income, property and capital gains taxes as far as these relate to earnings or capital from shipping. Companies only pay a so-called tonnage tax, i.e. a tax on a ship’s gross register tonnes corresponding to its age. However, an additional 15% withholding tax on the interest yields of bank deposits also applies to both companies and private individuals. This cannot be offset against anything and is not reimbursed. This is one reason why shipowners still want to keep all available liquidity in offshore accounts abroad nowadays. During the price explosion phase from 1999 to 2008, shipping companies were virtually swamped with liquidity. Hence the lack of interest in a declaration against authorities. Incidentally, something similar applies to other export and domestic economy sectors. This is the reason for the poor export performance of the hotel industry despite the 5 – star hotel boom and the reason for the poor export performance of other sectors. The withholding tax on bank deposits was introduced in 1991 and increased to 15% in 1992. It applies to all bank deposits of Greece-domiciled companies and resident private individuals, and therefore also to those abroad. This is a poorly designed tax, because it encourages tax evasion. In the hotel industry and other sectors of the economy, the normal corporation tax and capital levy on companies are in addition to the withholding tax.

After a boom up till 2008, shipping suffered a collapse like in the early 1980s. This also reflects the same sequence and causality as then: the double 2007/08 and again 2011 to 2014 oil shocks which rapidly followed each other, high orders for ships in the previous boom phase which resulted in fleet expansions in the middle of the slump and then overcapacity and the fall in freight rates. An important factor for the concentrated orders for ships was the increase in oil prices in the 2000s. Fuel costs are a major component of the total costs of ships. When oil prices increased from $20 - $25 per barrel in the 1990s to over $60 in 2005 – 08, many older ships became unprofitable. The newly ordered ships were usually much larger and had far more efficient engines which consumed less diesel or bunker fuel and allowed for a higher transport capacity. This was also a reason for the global investment boom. In addition to the massive capacity expansion, the weakening of the economic dynamic of transition economies, especially China’s, has also played a role in the merchant shipping crisis since 2008. Consequently, with respect to earnings, Greece’s most important export industry has been at the mercy of an unprecedented deflationary pressure since 2009. For example, freight rates for bulk transporters have fallen by over 90% since 2008 while freight rates for tankers have fallen by about 50%. No other country in the world has had an even remotely comparable collapse in export prices and earnings like Greece.

This had already occurred once in the early 1980s. However, then it mainly affected Greece’s fleet, which had fully participated in the supertanker boom of the 1970s. The crisis of recent years has not left Greece’s fleet untouched. However, other fleets were really hard hit. During the boom in bulk cargo carriers and container ships, they increased their investments in new ships massively. Among these are the fleets of Korea, China, Singapore and Germany, out of which China represents a special case. The Greek fleet has remained true to its traditional anti-cyclical behaviour. It has been investing heavily since 2012, now that the prices of new ships have fallen massively. And it is also buying relatively new ships from the secondary market in compulsory auctions and bankruptcies, which come at a fraction of the prices once paid in the newbuilding ordering. In contrast to the early 1980s, the Greek fleet has clearly improved its competitive position in the severe sector recession or even depression.

What applies to merchant shipping also applies to a lesser extent to the tourism sector. The export earnings of the tourism sector are also considerably underestimated in the balance of payments. This is due to a collection methodology which has changed since the adoption of the euro in 2002. It is very difficult to correctly record tourism services within a currency union. For this reason, since 2002, export earnings have been determined on the basis of surveys of tourists. Thus they are asked about their average daily expenses, the prices paid for overnight stays, etc. and the duration of their stay. Inferences are drawn from the statistical population using these surveys. This method – Frontier Travel Survey (FTS) – is also applied in the other periphery countries and many other European countries.

However, due to issues with evaluating surveys, it is unable to depict the tourism dynamic. Comparisons of export figures in the current account with other quantitative indicators of the tourism industry show that it expanded very strongly in the 2000s. None of this can be seen in the export figures. This is due to the inadequate recording of the data concerning overnight stays according to hotel categories. What the Greek tourism sector of the 2000s shows is a strong increase in five-star hotels bed capacity and overnight stays. Not only did this category expand, all other sectors stagnated (four – star hotels) or are clearly in decline (one to three – star hotels). Five – star hotels manage the highest output and added value per employee by far. Due to the steep growth of this sector through the structural shift into luxury hotels, the nominal and real turnover in the tourism sector on the whole grew rapidly even though the aggregate numbers of visitors and overnight stays between 2000 and 2009 on the whole grew insufficiently dynamically. Both main sectors of the Greek economy – merchant shipping and luxury hotels – are very capital- intensive and profited greatly from the low interest rates and improved financing conditions after the adoption of the euro. The luxury hotel sector also passed part of its export earnings through offshore centres abroad and not through its accounts in domestic banks. This is made possible through the tax optimisation of large hotel chains, accounts with large travel promoters and partly with online portals.

The real causes of Greece’s economic and structural crisis

According to official doctrine, Greece is bureaucratic, inefficient and characterised by excessively high costs. Some of this may be true, but all that has nothing to do with the current crisis. Greece’s crisis has nothing to do with poor competitiveness, excessively increased labour costs since the introduction of the euro and suchlike. It is mainly the result of inadequate economic statistics. The first, but not the only party responsible for this is the Greek central bank, which prepares the balance of payments and the international investment position. Since 1998/1999, the Bank of Greece could fall back on a unified form of the International Transaction Reporting System (abbreviated as ITRS).4 This is an end-of-day settlement reporting system and it covers all transactions with foreign countries carried out through Greek banks. The error lies in the politically motivated restraint with respect to shipowners, the real power in the country. Instead of demanding annual balance sheets certified by renowned auditors and to also link up the foreign accounts of shipowners and other economic sectors to the ITRS, the Bank of Greece left it at annual questionnaires with self-declarations.

The ECB, which calculates the current account balance and external position for the whole Eurozone and therefore is also answerable for the quality of this data, is also partly responsible. When Greece achieved enormous current account surpluses year on year and these were invested outside the eurozone through the export of capital, this also altered the Eurozone’s current account balance and external position. Therefore the ECB has an oversight function and has obviously never exercised it since the introduction of the euro. The erroneous statistics do not credit to the IMF which prepares the balance of payments from a global perspective and should compare or coordinate them. Although in its own documents, the IMF has been describing the earnings of the “missing fleet” as the main reason for the globally distortedly measured current account balances for decades, the IMF has not made any efforts to correct the Greek current account balance since the beginning of the Troika mission. The earnings of Greek shipowners are still flowing mainly into offshore foreign accounts in the Marshall Islands, Liberia, the Bermudas, Panama or in other tax havens which do not have any double taxation agreements with Greece. According to the IMF’s balance of payments manuals, these earnings belong to the export earnings of the country from which the shipping fleet is operationally controlled – therefore, in those of Greece. It does not matter under which flags the ships are registered. Incidentally, they do not appear in the balance of payments of these open registry nations, because the shipowners of these countries are not required to provide any information in this respect. It is still the same problem of the “missing fleet” as in the 1980s. In the 2000s, because of this and due to the incorrect recording of the tourism sector, Greece’s annual export earnings, up to a third of the recorded gross domestic product is suppressed. Even today, after the severe plunge in freight rates, the export earnings of shipping companies and the tourism sector are still massively underestimated.

Because only a small part of the freight earnings of shipping companies is recorded, the second dominant component of Greece’s current account is also massively underestimated. The shipowners’ expenditures fuelling abroad are also to be counted as imports. They are supposed to be recorded in the trade balance under imports and intermediate inputs of the shipping fleet. Just like freight rates, oil prices are extremely volatile. They increased about six-fold in US dollar terms between 1999 and 2012 and about fourfold in euro terms. For this reason, the energy bill (imports of energy less exports) completely dominates the growth of imports in the current account. Like freight rates, they have increased very steeply since 2004. However, since 2008, they have evolved quite differently from freight rates – they have risen again massively on an annual basis after a short and sharp decline in 2009. Incidentally, the price of fuel for ships (bunker oil) is highly correlated with the price of Brent crude.

In view of the weighting of merchant shipping, energy imports and the enormous cyclical variation, the growth of Greece’s current account and its balances is completely dominated by freight rates and oil prices. All other factors, and therefore the unit labour costs thus emphasised by the Troika, for instance, are irrelevant. What has been playing out in Greece’s current account since 2009 is a collapse of the most important export prices together with a simultaneous skyrocketing of important import prices. The increased energy bill is nothing other than a massive transfer payment abroad. On one hand, it depresses domestic consumption and on the other hand, it eats up the margins or net product in merchant shipping. This extremely negative price dynamic is the major reason for Greece’s crisis. It is an extreme external demand shock.

The second cause of Greece’s crisis is a shipping regulation system that has become obsolete and dysfunctional. A country which was actually achieved very high current account surpluses for a full decade should not be dependent on foreign short-term capital and consequently be fully exposed to exogenous shocks such as the 2008 financial crisis or the 2010 one. The merchant fleet’s tax privileges are only justified from a macroeconomic standpoint if this results in an inflow into domestic deposits. The banking system in Greece would then have been solidly financed. This second reason is also ultimately imputable to Greece. In this respect there was both the weakness of the Greek central bank, which did not develop any concept and any response to the problem of the financial stability of the banking sector and policy, which was probably driven by supposed interests of shipowners not wanting to alter anything regarding the tonnage tax and shipping regulation status quo. In this connection, the counterproductive effect of the withholding tax on domestic bank deposits must be emphasised. It led to the establishment of a second circulation abroad, mainly in offshore accounts, in addition to the domestic one. Due to this abnormal constellation, from 2004 onwards, domestic long-term loans were massively financed by short-term interbank funds from abroad. This led to fundamental balance sheet structure risks risk (ALM) and rendered the Greek banking system so vulnerable to withdrawal risks. The following diagram illustrates how external interbank obligations increased from 20 billion euro to 80 billion euro from 2004 to 2008. Non-bank deposits from outside the euro zone represent mainly shipowners’ accounts for their foreign-registered ships and hence actually domestic deposits.

The third cause lies in is the passive conduct of the Greek governments of the 2000s in fiscal and economic policy. And in this respect, revenue shortfalls dominate, not outrageous spending. The Simitis and Karamanlis governments did indeed make unnecessary expenditures for the 2004 Olympic Games in Athens or for the politically motivated distension of public sector employment. However, the origin of the Greek budget deficit lies in the revenue side. Even in the official EDP statistics, the percentage of the GDP constituted by government spending in the 2000s up to 2008 did not increase, but dropped. If consideration is given to the unrecorded growth in merchant shipping, luxury hotels and investment in building construction which is not or inadequately captured in the gross domestic product, then the spending proportion even fell quite considerably during the expansion phase.

However, what fell behind even more was the growth of tax revenue. A detailed analysis shows that two tax components underwent an actual structural break:

- Companies’ corporation tax and capital levy stagnated from 2000 to 2008 in absolute terms. Their percentage share of EDP-GDP fell sharply. Yet, they should have skyrocketed as in the second half of the 1990s. Their proportional share of the official EDP-GDP was not below average in comparison to other countries. During a boom as strong as that of the 2000s, such a very high, over-proportional increase in corporation tax would have been normal. This differentiates Greece fundamentally from all other countries, and even also from the other periphery countries. There, corporation tax revenue rose massively, also proportionately to the EDP-GDP.

- There was also a below – average increase in households’ income tax, i.e. less strongly than GDP. On top of that, Greece has the lowest income tax revenue relative to GDP in absolute terms, although the income of self-employed persons (40% of all workers) is included therein. In Greece, income tax represents only about 5% of EDP-GDP, but this is twice the European Union average. In the other countries, even in the other periphery countries, income tax revenues clearly increased stronger than GDP in the 2000s.

While the statistical findings are relatively simple, the economic explanation is more complex. What emerges clearly from this comparison is a pronounced special development on Greece’s part. This started around the turn of the century. It cannot be put down to discretionary alterations of tax rates and also not to the spending side. It represents a structural break with respect to the 1990s. Then tax revenues increased more than spending which led to primary surpluses’ of at least about 4% of EDP-GDP in the second half of the 1990s. In the 2000s, primary surpluses declined up till 2005 and changed into primary deficits in the best boom years of decades. The reasons for this structural break can only be indicated here, but cannot be discussed extensively and in depth:

- One possible hypothesis is disinflation and its effect on tax progression. In the 2000s, the inflation rate fell sharply, from double-digit rates in the 1990s to about 3.3% in the 2000s. The still only moderate increases in nominal incomes led thereby to slower progression to higher income tax brackets. This loss of the significance of bracket creep mainly affects income tax.

- The high inflation rates of the 1970s to 1990s which were always in two digits together with the tax rate bracket creep and the extreme social inequality also constitute an explanation for the widespread tax evasion and the large informal sector in Greece. They explain the low share of income tax in overall tax takings. The amount of the tax burden from VAT, income tax and other taxes and social security contributions is enormously high and favours tax evasion and unreported employment. In particular, only a small part of the income of self-employed persons, who constitute more than 30% of employed persons, is taxed. These high tax rates cause a collusion of interests between producers and consumers. When correctly taxed, a service quickly costs twice as much as a cash payment without evidence. Many households could barely afford dentists, their own homes or lawyers without tax evasion on the provider’s part.

- The wages and salaries regularly paid out are particularly influential for income tax revenues in Greece. They only rose moderately, in contrast to what the saga would like. The Labour Costs Index (LCI), which measures the labour costs of the workers required to pay social security contributions in the formal sector increased on average by about 4% per annum in the 2000s (2000 – 2009). The greater part of this increase occurred in the years up to 2003. If freight rates are correctly included as part of export prices in the GDP deflator, then wages and labour costs grew much less than output prices. However, the official GDP deflator or government spending expanded by over 7% per annum. This inevitably created a gap between tax revenue and government spending. In reality, wages did not grow too strongly, but rather insufficiently. Statistically recorded real wages practically stagnated in the 2000s, even though the economy experienced an enormous boom with real GDP growth rates of well over 4% per annum. If the GDP deflator had been correctly calculated, they actually fell from 2004.

- The success of the merchant fleet had negative tax consequences. The largest and by far the fastest-growing sector of the Greek economy pays practically no tax. This is part of the explanation. The other part relates to the induced copycat effect. During the stock market boom of the 2000s, more and more Greek shipping companies were listed on stock exchanges, whether this was the NYSE, the NASDAQ or also the Athens Stock exchange. At the beginning of the decade, the stock market regulator permitted the listing of Greek deep-sea shipping companies for the first time. Shares of this sector had been previously forbidden on the grounds of investor protection due to the high cyclical volatility. There was a reverse side to the listing at home and abroad; it was now possible for informed circles to look into the shipping companies’ profit growth. And what they saw was absolutely mind blowing. Middle-sized shipowners with good timing for fleet expansion could become billionaires within a few years. They paid practically nothing in taxes, neither corporation tax nor private income tax on this income or capital tax. This boom in revenues supported a domestic construction and real estate boom in Greece and in the Islands. Heavy domestic investment activity from reeders in tourism and above all in real estate occurred whereby offshore accounts facilitated tax evasion. Corruption scandals involving large shipowners were well-known, who bribed government members and insolently pushed through their interests outside shipping also and even against decisions of the highest court. This newly created publicity allegedly contributed to a fall in taxpayer honesty. It is incomprehensible why traders, building contractors, industrialist or hoteliers should pay taxes while nouveau riche shipowners with fantastic earnings and capital gains do not. The shipowners’ publicised success undermined taxpayer honesty. And companies in other sectors could also use the regulatory and tax-related optimisation potential of lawyers and trustees.

- The mass movement into the informal sector and the credit situation of the building and property sectors led to this sector paying little or no tax. Hundreds of thousands of Albanians immigrated to Greece in the 1990s and an additional hundreds of thousands of citizens of various nationalities immigrated in the 2000s to seek work here. Something similar also happened in the other periphery countries in the 2000s. In contrast to the other periphery countries, this immigration to Greece was not encouraged by the government, but rather occurred against the resistance of the authorities and policy. Given the fact that the borders were difficult to control the return policy was ineffective. The already large informal sector offered a lot of work, especially in the booming building sector, the hospitality and hotel industries, the agricultural sector and household services. The percentage of these illegal immigrants in overall employment increased quite considerably during the growth process of the 2000s. Due to their status of not possessing residence or work permits, they were in a weak position. Their supply was very flexible, and their employment could be extended without their wages increasing. For this reason, wages and labour costs actually paid in the whole economy grew much less strongly than those officially recorded in the formal sector.

One of the myth often and often repeated again is, that wage cost grew too strongly due to extraordinary demand. The graph above highlights the relation between construction costs and real estate prices in Greece. As opposed to public perception wage cost growth was very moderate after 1995 compared to real estate prices. Wage costs and other construction input cost such as materials were no major driver of real estate prices. Real estate prices grew like in Spain or in Ireland, but wage cost was definitely not an important factor. What made real estate prices explode, was cheap credit to households and the enormous inflow from shipping revenues. The reeders diversified and invested outside merchant shipping as well. In Greece, reeders often act as real estate developers in their home island or coastal region. They have knowledge of the real estate market, access to administration and key people. The graph reveals a huge widening of construction and real estate developer margins between 1995 and 2008.

However one fundamental factor differentiated the development in Greece from that of other periphery countries. In Spain, Ireland, Portugal and, with limitations, in Italy, the whole construction and property boom was financed by bank loans to construction companies and property developers. This, on the contrary, was not the case in Greece. Elsewhere, this loan financing created fiscal transparency. In Spain, for example, the construction and property sector contributed about 30% of the total tax revenues from the corporate sector in the 2000s. In addition, the number and the proportion of workers covered by social security in the sector increased strongly, resulting in a very large increase in tax revenues from the sector. In Greece, the construction boom achieved about the same extent as in Spain. However, a similar increase in the number or proportion of insured workers cannot be established.

- The Troika rightly stressed Greece’s tax code and the (politically willed) inefficient tax administration. This issue was made the crux of a reform of at least tax administration. The Greek tax code is a conglomeration of different taxes without an overall systematic conception. Time and again in the past, ad hoc specific taxes were introduced or the corresponding tax rates or opportunities for write-offs were altered in order to plug budget gaps in the short term or, conversely, to provide an economic policy stimulus or incentive for some interest group. An example of this is the tax on interest from bank deposits, organised as a withholding tax, which cannot be offset with interest expenses. Greece’s tax administration was deliberately kept on a tight budget; everything is based on manually completed tax declarations which are not systematically saved and are not easily comparable to other documents such as bank statements. The staff are insufficient and are insufficiently trained staff to cope with the complexity of the tax legislation. Tax officials were also directly corrupt and there is no possibility of sanctions such as immediate dismissal or the confiscation of property. This situation is an Eldorado for tax lawyers, trustees and investment advisers, who can identify countless loopholes and prepare guidelines for action with respect to tax avoidance and tax evasion.

This overall constellation is the reason for an immense increase in unreported employment, tax evasion and fiscal optimisation by companies in the boom of the 2000s. Greece had the strongest economic growth out of all the euro zone countries. There was a below-average increase in the wages and income of salaried workers. In particular, the extension of low wage sectors by the immigrants working as unreported workers in the informal economy cannot be overestimated. In reality, company revenues skyrocketed. Yet fully legal (merchant shipping) and partly illegal earnings are not reflected in the companies’ tax yields, which stagnated for a full decade in absolute terms.

The introduction of tonnage tax in 1957 was appropriate. It was the correct response to the nascent flags of convenience phenomenon. The tonnage tax represented a fiscal innovation which turned Greece into the most attractive location in the world for merchant shipping. It solved the problem of low corporate taxes and private income and property taxes at the same time. It attracted the big shipowners of Greek origins or nationality located in New York, London or Monaco back to Piraeus. The tonnage tax was also appropriate as a support program for start-ups. Tax advantages are an important instrument for attracting new industries, especially in periphery or poor countries or regions. It is something else altogether to guarantee these tax benefits in perpetuity to an economic sector which has become very competitive, as occurred in 1975 with the corresponding constitutional article. And it is still something else altogether to leave everything as it was in this sector, which has become an undisputed leader in the world market, during the biggest economic crisis for decades. The tonnage tax itself is not the problem. After all merchant shipping is highly capital intense, and it is one of the most risky and violent industries with devastating periods of sector debt deflations. Many other countries have followed the Greek (Cyprus, Malta) or a similar Dutch tonnage tax system and offer generous tax advantages as well. The problem is the mix of the tax with huge unrecorded offshore accounts. Revenues and outlays for ships flying under flags of convenience are typically recorded under accounts of jurisdictions without double taxation treaty with Greece. These accounts as such represent a key obstacle for the domestic money supply process in Greece. And they may be used for unrecorded transactions not just related to shipping but also to domestic economic activities in Greece. Historically, since the late 1950s up to the great boom in the 2000s the wealthy shipowners have been key promoters of tourism, real estate and other activities like banking and refineries in Greece for diversification reasons. Those shipping offshore accounts may be used to nourish offshore accounts related to those Greek domestic activities. Domestic transactions in Greece are then just partially settled through the Greek banking system and recorded in tax declarations. A secondary offshore or even shadow monetary circuit is used to circumvent tax collection in Greece. Real estate transactions for example may be registered in Greece, but only partially paid through domestic accounts. The rest may be settled through offshore accounts in locations without double tax treaties with Greece. In the present form, the tonnage tax system offers shipowners too much optionalities, particularly with respect to registration of foreign accounts and transactions thereon.

In Greece, this has led to generalised tax evasion on the one hand and to corruption in public life, on the other. Tax evasion is not just rooted in resistance from Ottoman times to paying tribute to a hated occupying power. Furthermore, the inadequate quality of the Greek state and its services does not suffice as an explanation. The massive stocking of the state with party members who are not at all qualified for employment in the public sector is an outrage. Especially when government employees only issue licenses or provide public services in return for bribes. However, the heart of the matter lies elsewhere: A society in which the richest and most economically successful entities are constitutionally allowed to pay no taxes corrodes public taxpayer honesty especially when this is publicised and abused for other purposes. Added to this is the fact that shipowners use legal constructions and unreported offshore accounts to cancel out the withholding tax that they owe, even on their foreign accounts. And above all, not least when important exponents of this view conduct themselves in such a way in economic activities outside shipping, as if only fools paid taxes. The first-generation shipowners who immigrated to Greece from London, New York, Monaco or Switzerland in the 1960s and 1970s and the heirs and relations of these families have had a decisively influenced development in tourism, real estate and in the financial sector or in other sectors of the modern economy in Greece. This is something positive in itself. This is how a diversification of the shipping companies’ currency earnings into other export industries or into the domestic economy occurred or occurs. However, important protagonists of today’s generation also represent shining examples for the exact opposite. They treat the Greek state like a banana republic.

At first glance, insufficient tax revenue appears to be easy to remedy. The shipowners simply must be properly taxed. The first problem is that Greek merchant shipping consists of so-called cross traders. In contrast to other large fleets, they do not serve the domestic market primarily, but rather provide transport between third countries. In this respect, they are not linked to Greece and may operate from London, Monaco, Geneva or other centres. If something consequential with respect to taxes is carried out at the level of corporate taxation, then it must be coordinated at the overall European or even global level. Otherwise this would simply end with the loss of this leading economic sector in Greece. The second problem is that time for this is rather unsuitable. Shipping companies are in a deep crisis similar to that of the early 1980s. In such a situation, tax increases are inappropriate. It should be noted that there is a certain amount of scope in the long term as soon as the economic position recovers. The government halved the tonnage tax in 2002, just at the time when the largest boom of all time in merchant shipping started. This is a classical example of a wrong pro-cyclical fiscal policy. The tax rate should have been maintained at the time or rather increased than reduced. This has had consequences up to today: the tax rate for the tonnage tax is not constant and the tax per ship rises annually by about 4%. Otherwise, the tonnage tax would be constantly falling in real terms. If this tax rate is halved once, then there would be an increase of about 4% annually in the subsequent years from a very low starting level and it would therefore be lower in absolute terms. Raising the tonnage tax in the medium term to the original level or the level path does not appear to be inappropriate. Also extending the tonnage tax to ships flying foreign flags has proved to be a clever move. This arbitrage opportunity was restricted thereby. The real key task with respect to taxation is thorough registration and supervision of offshore accounts of shipowners and other economic agents. with huge fines in case of abuse for unrecorded domestic transactions.

However, the essential contribution that the shipping companies should make for the foreseeable future is not at the level of taxes, but rather to the money supply process and precisely in the present situation. History is necessary to understand this. Since 1980 Greece has developed in the wrong direction, in this context, definitely in a double or triple sense.

The circumstances in the public sector which are reminiscent of Latin America, with politically motivated recruitment and an inefficient, bureaucratic, inflated and corrupt government apparatus represent the first evident level. They go far back, but have been greatly accelerated by the decisions and course settings of Andreas Papandreou’s government in the 1980s. They should not be discussed further here. What would be required is a mix of reforms at the level of legislation, judicial, administrative and tax authorities. The Troika partially addressed some of these issues. The key default, the secondary money circuit abroad, was not tackled at all. Due to the short-term budget targets, a real administrative reform could never be implemented.

A second level concerned the economic policy response to the serious crisis in the shipping industry at the beginning of the 1980s. The Papandreou government decided on a fiscal expansion and an aggressively accommodating monetary policy with the devaluation of the drachma and a financing of the expansionary fiscal policy through the printing press. In principle, this expansionary fiscal policy was correct. In hindsight, this policy was wrong as an overall solution, because it did not take into consideration the specific currency exposure of the merchant fleet. Devaluation is useless if the revenues and the majority of the costs of the country’s largest and most important export industry are in US dollars. Furthermore, the effect of the strong increase in the labour costs of Greek semen even undermined .

Therefore, a third cause concerns merchant shipping itself and its embedding in the overall economy. From the late 1950s to 1980, the shipping industry drove the country forward. High foreign currency earnings, strong employment gains in a highly productive and well-paying sector led to multiplier and backward and forward linkage effects in line with Albert O. Hirschmann’s theory. However, there was a structural break after 1980, with long-term consequences. In particular, the number of Greek seamen fell from about 100,000 in 1980 to 35,000 in 1986 and to less than 20,000 within 20 years. Looking back, the best solution would have been to pay the seamen in USD instead of in drachmas. Yet, who can blame employees for wanting to be paid in the currency of their lf or their families and not wanting to take any currency risk? Due to the shipping companies’ severe crisis at the time, the previously tight dovetailing between the world-market oriented export sector and the overall economy slackened instead of becoming stronger as is usual in a growth process. Greek shipowners registered their ships under flags of convenience so that they could avoid the trades union – established wages of Greek seamen and sign up cheap workers from the Philippines and India as seamen. Furthermore, they no longer had to insure them with the seamen’s pension fund. The number of Greek seamen in the shipping industry fell rapidly. The shipyards lost their significance as suppliers for new construction and repairs, given the shipping companies’ severe crisis.

The adoption of the euro created an improved dovetailing with the domestic economy again. Greek banks could make increased loans for the financing of the merchant fleet. Insurers and other specialised service providers such as development and consulting firms, suppliers and maintenance companies and shipbrokers grouped themselves in a cluster around Piraeus for this purpose. However, the fundamental problem remained the shipping companies’ extraordinary currency exposure. Up till 2001, the merchant shipping industry was dollar-denominated in a small open economy with its own currency and a banking system which in contrast to New York was underdeveloped, highly regulated and was also still characterised by decades-long rigid capital controls. An unbridgeable area of conflict was created as a result. Since the introduction of the euro, merchant shipping is still dollar – denominated, but in a small open economy in a currency union with the second most important currency in the world and also with a banking system with all technical characteristics and solutions as offered by New York or London. This opens up completely new possibilities.

With respect to labour costs, nowadays, payments in USD could be combined with a compensation mechanism (optionality) in the event of adverse currency developments. Given the development of options techniques in the currency markets, such a solution is easy to structure. This was not possible in the late 70s and early 80s, and definitely not in relation to a marginal currency like the drachma. Still, today, the merchant shipping industry’s wage problem is a priority. While inflation in Greece is no longer in double digits year after year, Greek seafarer wages are too high to allow large scale recruitments. What should be lowered, are initial salaries for seamen, in order to allow higher recruitments of Greek seamen and higher staff later on.

Greece’s much more fundamental core problem is that the recycling of foreign currencies from shipping exports does not work properly. They are mainly held in USD accounts abroad, mostly in the name of offshore legal entities without double taxation agreements with Greece. Ships under flags of convenience often or even mostly are registered under companies of respective legislation. This has negative consequences for the banking sector. Most European countries are deeply integrated into the world market. Their companies send about 50% to 70% of exports to Europe and are mainly paid in euro, sometimes even for deliveries outside Europe. Most of their costs are also incurred in euro. These companies can hold their accounts in the domestic banking system without any problems and have all services available. This constitutes a reasonable requirement for a workable domestic banking system. There is no fundamental disruption of asset and liability management in the banking system.

In contrast, in Greece, the earnings of the country’s largest export industry by far and its most important economic sector lie in offshore accounts abroad which are denominated in dollars. Such capital export also partly occurs in the hotel industry, especially among the four – star and five –star hotels, mostly in euro accounts. This is disadvantageous to the domestic banking system. A credit expansion in the system must almost inevitably be financed with a short-term capital import. This makes the country highly dependent on capital inflows from abroad. From the 1980s until the introduction of the euro, the remittances of Greeks who had emigrated and were living abroad and the payments from EU funds were necessary to cover the current account deficits from commercial payments. Emigrant remittances dried in the 2000s and the credit expansion accelerated, with the result that after the introduction of the euro, mainly short-term capital imports in the euro interbank market to had to be brought in to plug gaps. Currently, after several years of severe banking crises, the whole Greek banking system is financed by the ECB to a considerable extent, which is unsustainable over the medium and long term. Technically it goes like this: the banks hold liabilities with the Greek central bank. The latter, on its own part, then builds up obligations vis-a-vis other central banks in the target mechanism.

In the 1950s, it was correct to grant shipowners tax benefits and to refrain from imposing on them any obligation to bring revenues from shipping companies to Greece. At that time, Greece did not have a liberal and competitive banking system which could have guaranteed a cost-effective and efficient service for dollar transactions. Today, it is foolish to continue this optionality for shipowners and hence this business model. Tax benefits should only be granted if, conversely, shipowners bring their revenues to accounts in Greece-domiciled banks. In this respect, three measures need to be implemented urgently: first, the abolition of the withholding tax on domestic bank deposits, second, the obligations for shipowners operating from Greece to hold their liquidity or the greater part thereof inside the country and thirdly: rigorous supervision and monitoring of compliance with this obligations and this within the framework of the balance of payments statistics organised by the Greek central bank.

Europe’s leaders were surprised when Greece had to ask for help in 2010. Therefore they cannot be reproached for the first response. It was essentially based on the interpretations and prescription that the future IMF chief economist, Olivier Blanchard, had developed in several articles between 2001 and 2007 for Portugal: The concept of internal devaluation. It also was connected to Germany’s supposed experiences with the Agenda 2010.

In 2010/11, the task seemed relatively simple and clear. The diagnosis was so clear, that more precise quantitative clarifications seemed superfluous. Greece had burgeoning double deficits in its budget and in its current account. This is the classical situation in which the IMF is called in. Diagnoses are quickly made in such a situation. The country was suffering from a fiscal policy that was way too expansionary which had led to excessive demand and pushed the current account into deficit.

In content and direction, the catalogue of measures proposed and implemented by the Troika is the IMF’s standard policy. This Washington consensus contains a mix or combination of measures and targets which has been the classic IMF prescription for balance of payments crisis situations since the Latin American debt crisis of the 1980s. Its most important components are:

- Reduction of domestic demand through fiscal, monetary and lending policies.

- Drastic currency devaluation and exchange rate correction as a countermove.

- Budget cuts including wages, social welfare benefits, subventions, etc., often price subsidies for basic food items also.

- Privatisation of public corporations and establishments.

- Debureaucratisation.

The specific or adjusted therapy for Greece concerned internal devaluation policy. As Blanchard’s theory goes, in a currency union, adjustments can only be made thorough domestic wages and prices and not through exchange rates. This internal devaluation is supposed to reduce unit labour costs and lead to an export boom. The second thrust is a relatively short-term balancing of the budget and the consolidation of public debt relative to nominal GDP. The object is to obtain a lasting primary surplus. A primary surplus is defined as spending minus government revenues excluding interest payments. The measures in this respect turned out to be draconic for Greece in the quantitative dimension.

The first consequence was the drastic increase in VAT and other indirect taxes and levies. This is a central element of the internal devaluation policy. The aim is twofold: firstly, to generate relatively short-term higher tax revenues and secondly, to lower domestic consumption. According to the theoretical idea, this should not have any effect on exports. In the simple theoretical model, exports are generally not subject to VAT and this can constitute an input tax deduction for export industry supplies. According to the basic idea, the drastic increase in VAT rates should only lower domestic consumption and thereby reduce imports. The VAT should therefore push the current account balance into surplus while mainly reducing imports.

The second consequence is the fall in nominal wages. The drastic reduction in wages is a second core element of the internal devaluation policy. The idea is to thereby reduce labour costs in order to make the export industry more competitive and stimulate exports. The efforts to reduce wages were focused on the public sector and on the minimum wage. Both were assigned to wage management. In addition, wage reductions in the public sector would directly reduce government spending. Additional measures were also implemented in the labour market in order to be able to reduce wages and make layoffs easier.

Incorrect data are also the seeds of every serious crisis. The protagonists refer to indicators and act in accordance therewith. All of Greece’s statistics would have had to be turned on their heads. Then the real cause could have been identified. Of all countries it is the one with by far the highest growth in exports in Western Europe that was characterised as a weakling and bureaucratically ossified, high-wage and with chronically weak productivity growth and everyone believed it. An international armada of experts, advisers and specialised institutions – IMF, ECB, and EU – are monitoring the country and are unable to find out the main problem. No other dominant export sector of any western European country except the Norwegian oil industry even saw its selling prices increase four to seven-fold within 10 years. These selling prices are highly standardised freight rates which can be downloaded on a daily, monthly, quarterly and annual basis from any data service such as Bloomberg or Reuters. These are not complex structured products which can barely be deciphered. In contrast: the Baltic Dry Index, a price index for the freight rates of bulk carriers and therefore representative of one of the two main areas of activity of Greek shipping companies (roughly 50% of total deadweight tonnage), is one of the 10 to 20 most observed and commented indicators of the world economy. It is the best early indicator of the growth of the world economy, especially that of emerging economies. In addition to the price explosion in the 2000s, there was also a capacity build-up and high productivity gains through a renewal and expansion specifically of the Greek fleet. In relation to Greece’s almost exponential export growth in the 2000s, that of Germany, the “world champion” of exports, effectively was modest. By 2008, Greece would probably have recorded very high current account surpluses if the statistics had been correctly calculated.

Since then a decline which is unique by international and exceptional by historic standards has occurred due to the collapse in freight rates. It is exceptional that the export prices of a country’s most important export industry trigger a severe deflation. A whole range of observations are associated thereto:

- The incorrectly prepared current account encouraged the interpretation that labour costs supposedly rose too high since the introduction of the euro. This is nonsense. Shipping is a very capital-intensive industry with fewer direct employees nowadays than in the past. This is 15 – 20 persons per ship who are mostly paid in the currency of their home countries nowadays. The majority of seamen on Greek ships under foreign flag are from the Philippines and India and are paid very low wages. Only a part of seamen mostly under Greek flag and the management staff are Greeks or Greece-domiciled. So is the administrative staff. Intermediate inputs are partly obtained from Greece. However, with reference to cost factors, shipping is predominantly dollar – denominated. It is dominated by capital costs (Libor plus spread, amortisation and depreciation of ships). Fuel costs, also incurred in USD are crucial, especially when oil prices are very high. In Greece, even tonnage tax is paid in USD. Other operating costs are a fraction of the total costs and barely rose in the 2000s.

- Therefore, the proposal to use wage reductions and austerity in Greece overall to improve the competitiveness of its most important export industry is quite absurd.

- The really decisive competitive factors for both merchant shipping and the hotel industry are low and stable interest rates and a flexible credit supply. In the shipping industry short term interest rates (Libor plus spread) are the normal market conditions. This competitive factor would be drastically worsened with volatile interest rates which would be associated with a return to the drachma. However, the situation with an undercapitalised banking system and periodic panic attacks in financial markets which has been continuous since 2010 also has devastating effects on the country’s two leading export industries.

What the policy of indirect devaluation in a currency union propagated by Blanchard does not take into consideration at all is mainly private and public indebtedness in particular and the risks arising therefore. The standard IMF prescription was developed for emerging economies where the private non-financial sector is practically debt free. Only the government and, in the case of the Asian crisis, the banks, were externally indebted. In Greece like in the other periphery countries, this requirement is not present. Admittedly, private indebtedness in the periphery countries has traditionally been modest. Greece built up practically the whole of the private indebtedness existing today to banks in the years following the adoption of the euro. In this respect, about half of it is owed by households, mainly for mortgages, and companies. Exactly the same process happened everywhere in the periphery. Incidentally, it was also repeated belatedly in the transition economies of eastern and central Europe which joined the European Union in 2004 and 2007. In Greece, the credit expansion was not focused on the domestic economy exclusively, but covered both the export industry, mainly shipping and tourism, and the domestic economy. A deflationary course in such an environment of high indebtedness and high loan to value ratios comprises quite different framework conditions and risks than in earlier episodes.

Monetary Policy: The failed debt write-off leads to a systemic banking crisis

What differentiates Greece from the other countries under the Troika’s regime is the special relationship with monetary policy. In 2008 Greece initially escaped the interbank crisis. However, the severe shipping crisis and cash drain refrained reeders from further investing into domestic economic activities such as real estate. In 2010, the interbank crisis triggered a bank lending freeze like in all other periphery countries. The withdrawal of interbank funds meant that the banks could only make much reduced new loans for balance- sheet – related reasons. Yet, in Greece, the dangerous dependency on the foreign interbank market suddenly expanded into a systemic banking crisis. The debt write-off established in 2011 and the subsequent actions of the Troika were responsible for this. The idea goes back to an initiative of the German finance minister Schäuble. The debt write-off was supposed to have made the public debt sustainable after it has risen to over 170% of the nominal GDP according to the EDP procedure. With this size, it was rated as being no longer sustainable. It was actually much lower, because exports had been drastically underestimated by the Bank of Greece since the 1960s. Due to the balance of payments data, GDP was in this respect calculated too low by the Greek statistics directorate and Eurostat. Furthermore, construction investment suffered from wrong measurement methodology too and was massively underestimated as well. The budget deficits in reality also never actually attained the size recorded by the EDP procedure. The 2011 debt write-off would have been unnecessary and not opportune if the balance of payments and GDP had been conceptually calculated correctly.

The write-off was supposed to restore credibility and ease the country’s access to the capital market again. At first, a 29% waiver by creditors was mooted in summer 2011, but the EU heads of government finally decided on a waiver of about 53.5% of the existing government bonds. The existing obligations were later in two major steps exchanged for new ones. Together with the reduced interest rates and extended terms/maturity dates, the newly issued debt effectively entailed a loss of about 75% for the existing holders of public debt. Due to the predictable write-down of public debt (credit event), the Greek banking system was immediately and directly pushed into serious equity deficits.5 IFRS accounting rules require a credit event – a missed interest payment and even more so, in the event of a debt write-off - to be immediately and directly reflected in profit statements and in the equity capital. The bank then has a reduction in equity because the security must be immediately written down to the (reduced) market value. Greek banks held a considerable portion of their own country’s public debt. Those holdings however were not above average by international standards. The banks’ holdings of government bonds in the system reached about the same extent as the total recorded equity capital. Due the write-off that had become technically necessary, a great deal of the banks’ equity was consequently lost. For this reasons, various Greeks banks were already recording negative equity by the end of 2011. An insufficient equity situation had dramatic consequences for banks. Since the introduction of the Basle Regulations for banking capital, credit and other bank asset portfolio decisions have been directed by equity capital regulations. If equity is insufficient, the balance sheet must be reduced. This is achieved though a lending freeze.

The Troika foresaw this and pledged the whole amount of the write-off for the re-accumulation of capital for the banks from the EFSF as part of the second support program. It was also planned that the banks’ accumulated credit losses would be covered therewith. However, these amounts would not be paid over immediately, but would be made available in an operation over several quarters, two years in total. These payments were also part of the arsenal of means of exerting pressure that the Troika started with respect to its Greek negotiating partners. “Liquidity for reforms” was the motto. Moreover, in the end, the whole amount was not paid and not at once, but staggered in tranches. Furthermore, the Greek banking system was subjected to a massive restructuring in order to lower the funds. The whole banking system was compulsorily merged into four large system-relevant banks in several operations because effects of scale and lower finance requirements for the creditor countries were expected thereby. The refinancing was carried out and concluded in partial operations in the second quarter of 2012 and 2013 respectively. The key point was that the old existing government bonds at these points in time were exchanged against new ones. At the same time the recapitalization only happened. What the Troika, more precisely the leading German ministry of finance did not take into consideration, was the accounting impact. From the announcement at the end of 2011 till Q2 2012 the Greek banking system had practically no equity at all, and between Q2 2012 and Q2 2013 largely insufficient equity. The equity capital was re-established only then. But what happened, that it was completely insufficient due to the fact, that non-performing and bad loans had risen to outrageous levels. By early 2014, it was already clear that there was too little equity in the banking system again, due to the steep increase in non-performing and bad loans.

The banks usually entered government bonds into their investment books and mostly booked them as Held to Maturity (HtM) also. (HtM was abolished under the IFRS 9 which was adopted in 2014 and replaced by booking under “amortised cost”). HtM means that the bank intends and is able to hold this asset till maturity. Otherwise the auditor would not accept it. Conversely, rate fluctuations of HtM securities during the holding period are not visible in either profit&loss statements or in the equity capital. Hence, a bank can earn money because it does not have to cover rate fluctuations (volatility) in the bank or investment books with its own equity. There are two drawbacks to this practice:

HtM assets usually cannot be simply covered with derivatives. Accounting rules require a high degree of correlation between the alteration of derivatives and the underlying asset, proof of which frequently and precisely in volatile markets cannot be provided. Without hedge accounting, the alterations in the value of derivatives were fully reflected in both profits and equity. Bank managements shrank from this. Therefore, HtM securities are difficult for banks to cover. That was one of the reasons for the move from IAS 39 to IFRS 9.

The Troika also called for capital injections. However, the Greek government rejected this, mainly because the donor countries attached new requirements of restrictive measures to it. What the government did instead was to convert deferred tax assets into directly enforceable tax credits against the Greek state. The EBA just asked, that those credits should be paid in cash instead of by issuing bonds in case of need. It was calculated as tier 1 capital despite Basel III restricting this practice. Despite these accounting gimmicks, the ECB stress test in autumn 2014 revealed that only one of the four merged big banks had sufficient equity capital. And this stress test had a whole series of design flaws, which, however, was true of the whole Euro zone and cannot be discussed here. Incidentally, the whole restructuring is self service by the owners of the surviving banks, who often snapped up the large branch networks of competitors for ridiculously small sums and in addition were given high guarantees from the government and tax privileges for up to 30 years. Yet, these were only side issues then, but will be important for the situation now. What is crucial from a macroeconomic perspective is the fact that for many years, Greek banks operated at times without or at any rate with very little equity. They did not comply with the stipulated solvency requirements, which are anyway inadequate for crisis situations. In addition, they were in a merger process and in complex restructurings in order to be assigned to these four groups. Fresh lending was highly restricted in this environment. For this reason, monetary policy was ultra-restrictive from the middle of 2011 onwards and strangled tens of thousands of companies with hundreds of thousands of employees, including many small businesses whose credit tap was abruptly turned off. Only larger companies could access fresh lending at sufficient degree. The Troika’s procedure caused a huge systemic banking crisis. Such a crisis is defined by the IMF as a loss of the greater part of a banking system’s equity. This also applies to Cyprus incidentally. Due to historically close linkages, Cypriot banks traditionally invested in Greek government bonds. Their equity capital in the whole system was also practically wiped out with the debt write-off - without any compensation at all.

The debt write-off and bank restructuring imposed by the creditors set off a sequential further erosion of banks’ equity capital and creditworthiness. The general liquidity crisis held the economy in an iron grip during a systemic credit crunch which has lasted for years. Bills can no longer be paid. Suppliers go bankrupt when customers can no longer pay and a chain reaction spreads through the whole economy. Many borrowers first became insolvent and went bankrupt not long after. With this, the percentage of nonperforming and bad loans increased abruptly. On the other hand, both non-performing and bad loans have to be covered with massively higher risk weights and equity by the banks with the result that risk capital also eroded further after the recapitalisation. The credit crunch, liquidity crisis, fiscal policy austerity, further increasing bad loans, insufficient equity, etc, formed a vicious circle.

Superficial assertions that only serve Troika exponents must be firmly countered. In Greece, the insolvency of the whole banking system cannot be attributed to the excessive lending in the boom. Greek banks had well-diversified loan portfolios. Loans to the construction industry and property developers were only a side issue in Greece. In Ireland, Spain or in Portugal as well as in Eastern Europe those construction and property developer loans hat dominated the steep growth of credit to non-financial corporations. In Greece, according to the usual indicators, lending was not excessive also. The “loan to deposit ration” (LTD), i.e. the relationship between loans and domestic customer funds had not risen to 170% in the expansion as opposed to the other periphery countries during the boom. Conversely, what actually obtained was the massive dependency on the external interbank market built up since 2004. This led to the 2010 credit crunch. Greek banks were also solidly provided with equity capital. What made the banking system insolvent practically overnight was solely the 2011 debt write-off which was undertaken with good intentions, but erroneously, due to the data position, and the recapitalisation which was carried out in a staggered and insufficient fashion instead of immediately. In 2011 the percentage of non-performing loans was at ratio slightly above 10%. This ratio rose to quite above 30% till the end of 2013 and are now at a horrible 50%.

The systemic banking crisis in Greece was concealed by several effects. This is why the dominant role of monetary policy in Greece’s economic crisis has been removed from public discussion.

- The central role of the ECB’s monetary policy for the euro crisis is generally underestimated because most economists misunderstand the way monetary policy works. Since the introduction of the Basle regulations for common equity, the way monetary policy works or its stepwise transmission mechanisms have fundamentally changed. The monetary policy credit channel has become more important, definitely dominant and has been remoulded completely. It is not taken into consideration or even particularly understood by the ECB and the Eurozone’s decision makers and practically all economists taking part in the discussion. The focus is too much on the liabilities side of bank balance sheets because this is standard in the traditional literature on the money supply process. And the ECB and the national central banks were definitely or even very active on the liabilities side.

- With the ECB’s approval, the Greek central bank financed the banks with high amounts of over 100 billion euro through emergency loans, the so-called Emergency Loan Assistance (ELA), in order to offset the contraction of deposits. Deposits declined rapidly for three reasons: 1) Just like in the other periphery countries, the harsh credit contraction logically led to an accompanying contraction of deposits. It was not only deposits from foreigners and interbank funds from abroad which declined but also the deposits from domestic non-bank sectors. 2) Prosperous Greeks shifted their money abroad. Therefore a form of capital flight started, on the one hand out of the fear of an exit from the currency union and for reasons of tax evasion on the other hand. 3) The drastic fall in income through unemployment and tax increases forced many Greeks to exhaust their savings.

- The ECB provided liquidity for the banking system with its remarkable operations – LTRO – for the whole zone and beyond that through the target mechanism. The assurance given by its president, Draghi that everything would be done and would suffice to save the euro also had an effect on the liabilities side of bank balance sheets.

- The interest rates on government bonds also dropped back to normal levels also in Greece. Most analysts without an accurate knowledge of monetary economics attributed this to the effect of an expansionary monetary policy.

- The whole refinancing operation was seen as a – temporary – success, especially with reference to the effects on the financial markets. Unlike other such debt write-offs in Argentina, it did not lead to a financial panic in the whole of Europe, but rather to an easing at first. Today, it is obvious to all that the Greek public debt – and those of the other periphery countries – has not become more sustainable.

The effect of the refinancing and the debt write-off for Greece amounted to an extremely restrictive monetary policy for Greece and Cyprus. The special thing about Greece is the extent to which investments in construction collapsed and dropped still further. Investments in construction did not collapse in this way in any other euro country. The contribution to the fall in the officially recorded GDP, ex-post statistically measured, is extraordinary. More than 50% is directly attributable to the fall in investments in construction, the majority of which was in housing construction. The mechanism established in this respect differs from the other periphery countries in the credit crunch as regards construction companies and property developers. There are indeed such mechanisms, but they are not as important. The decisive factor is the inability of banks to grant long-term loans such as mortgages to households or companies. Empirically, it is the same way everywhere – investments in construction, especially in housing, are extremely sensitive with regards to interest rates and credit conditions, particularly the supply of credit. Furthermore, just like in most other European countries, investments in construction in Greece are still incorrectly calculated from a conceptual standpoint. The collapse was actually still greater and occurred from a much higher level and the contribution to the fall in GDP was also proportionally higher. Shipping, tourism and construction investment were the main sectors in Greece’s post-war economic growth.

The point is that the whole refinancing action was carried out in order to help Greece. This intention was surely at the origin of the whole operation. The issue in this case was not the rescue of the German or French banking sectors. The banks there did have to accept write-offs of 75% of their Greek government bonds. In addition, the operation was backed up with a second bailout package of about 120 billion euro, resulting in a total of 240bn euro. Added to this were the facilities through the Bank of Greece which the latter refinanced with the ECB through target loans. This amount was recorded at about 50 billion euro for the end of 2014, but is now much higher, clearly over 100 billion. In addition, about 5 billion euro in LTRO funds is still in Greek banks. The repayment of these ECB funds is hardly guaranteed and must be considered lost if Greece leaves the euro. Enormously large sums of taxpayers’ funds could hardly be burned more efficiently within a short period even in the donor countries. What was done wrongly in Greece was the debt write-off and the belated and complex form of the bank recapitalisation. It was the combination of an ultra-restrictive monetary policy – a systematic banking crisis – coupled with an ultra-restrictive fiscal policy which pushed the country into the biggest depression of any developed economy since the 1930s.

This should be compared with the restructurings of the financial sectors in the U.S.A. and in the United Kingdom in 2008/09 in order to explain what other options would have been. In late 2008/ early 2009, system-relevant banks in the U.S.A. had their capital holes plugged with a compulsory recapitalisation by the government through a taking of equity stakes. In so doing, no questions as to whether the banks needed the increased equity capital or not were asked. Banks which had come to grief were assigned to other big banks in central bank cloak and dagger operations in which the Fed took over a considerable portion of the toxic assets. Morally and ethically, in retrospect some acquiring banks were made into enormous power centres without much effort or expense on their own part. Many smaller banks were efficiently wound up. The fact that decisions were taken very rapidly and on a large scale and action was taken without long due diligence with the result that the acquiring and the remaining surviving banks quickly had sufficient equity was essential to the system’s survival. The end effect was that at that time, the restructuring came with no direct costs to the taxpayer. Certainly, the form of the restructuring led to a very problematic concentration of power with a few megabanks within a few months. One may wonder if their conduct and business practice are sufficiently and properly regulated. In the arch-capitalist UK, major banks in difficulty were unflinchingly nationalised without further ado, their shareholders practically expropriated, their management replaced and new managements were hired for restructuring with an attractive incentive structure and monitored with an oversight system set up by external experts. Each time new equity capital holes appeared, the banks were promptly and generously recapitalised. The bailout of the banking sector was complemented by an immediate zero interest-rate policy from the Bank of England from 2009 which it has maintained till now. In the United Kingdom, this zero interest-rate policy was all the more effective as, just like in the periphery countries and in Greece specifically, mortgage interest rates are variable and are linked to the bank rate with a spread. In the U.S.A., the largest economic stimulus package in history was added for the stabilisation of final demand.

In both cases, the system could be stabilised in this way, a restructuring of the banking sector implemented in the medium term and an economic recovery initiated. In this respect, the government took over high risks, but also a potential for future capital gains. On the other hand, in Greece, the Troika implemented an endless haggling about the results of negotiations in quite different matters, restructuring of the whole sector and about a cheap bookkeeping solution for the creditors, but one which is not possible from an economic standpoint. This haggling has not yet been concluded as of today, but is ongoing. Only with more commitment this time. Since at least middle of 2011, the banking sector as a whole was undercapitalised or at times even insolvent for years. The effect of this is that the credit channel in Greece has been almost completely closed for more than three years and this is why the monetary policy brutally accelerated and deepened the recession. The correct thing would have been to recapitalise the banks immediately and generously, but not without conditions. A subsequent due diligence should have been quickly carried out in order to determine which banks are able to survive and for which ones another solution – nationalisation or compulsory merger – must be sought. The banks’ equity situation should not be deficient at any time. The idea of saving donor countries’ funds or to use the funds earmarked for the recapitalisation of the banks perpetually as a means of exerting pressure for was erroneously planned from a conceptual standpoint, and from the beginning. Currently, the situation in the banking sector in Greece is several times worse than in summer of 2011. The banks are also undercapitalised and insolvent after the restructuring of the the whole sector and recapitalisation. The problems with the burgeoning increase in “bad loans” are insoluble without a further massive injection of new funds from donor countries. Deposits have collapsed further, with the result that the banking system’s balance sheet can no longer be financed without far-reaching central bank credit. Greece is currently in the largest systemic banking crisis that a country has experienced since the 1930s.

Fiscal policy accelerates the economy’s downward spiral – in addition to the standard demand effect

Fiscal policy usually has an outstanding place in the criticism of the Troika’s policy. It is argued that fiscal policy supposedly resulted in an excessively strong collapse of economic activities through classic demand effects (tax increases, spending cuts). On the other hand, the Troika’s representatives argue that the stabilisation of public debt can only be achieved if lasting primary surpluses are achieved as rapidly as possible. Fiscal policy is usually incorrect evaluated by both sides because its distorting effects are not taken into consideration. With respect to government debt, the domestic sector plays a dominant role through several channels for the tax base: The periphery countries in general and Greece in particular are characterised by a tax system where taxes are levied mainly on consumption and formal employment. Income from property and – sometimes (shipping companies’) – capital gains on the one hand and informal employment on the other are largely untapped and anyway not comparable with the Anglo-Saxon or central European countries. Tax evasion by self-employed persons and companies is widespread. While formal employment and consumption were primarily and massively reduced by the restrictive monetary and fiscal policies as well as through direct interventions in the labour market (“labour market reforms”), the tax base was directly reduced and partly destroyed:

- The reduction in nominal wages by over 20%, an avowed objective of the Troika, had a direct consequence. The lower nominal wages led to directly lower direct tax yields and social security contributions. Direct income taxes and social security contributions increased overall as a percentage of nominal wages. If wages fall, tax revenues and social security contributions drop. This drop is over-proportional, due to a tax system with progressive tax rates.

- Companies’ corporation tax and capital levies have completely collapsed because the country fell into a depression.

- The restrictive monetary and fiscal policies also led to smaller revenues for the government from VAT and turnover tax due to falls in real wages and especially to the massively declining employment. As the periphery countries do not have any unemployment insurance or only weakly developed ones, the fall in employment and real incomes affected private consumption almost immediately. In Greece, the state pays unemployment benefits for one year and then nothing more, not even welfare benefits. However, this is only if the employee had previously paid social security contributions for at least two years. Self-employed persons or unreported workers in the informal sector receive nothing when they lose their commissions or employment.

- The increased VAT turned out to be a debacle for exports which, according to a simple theoretical model, should not have been the case. For Greece, like other periphery countries, tourism represents an exception. In this sector there are hotels and prices of overnight stays and restaurants on one hand and on the other hand cafes, bars and other services – transport, entrance fees to museums, other cultural events or performances are subject to VAT and admittedly, sometimes at reduced rates. However, in Greece, these reduced rates were also increased in 2010 and at the beginning of 2011. The rates for overnight stays in hotels rose from 4.5% to 6.5% and those for transport and for restaurants and cafes rose from 9% to 13%. A 23% VAT rate was likewise imposed again on prepared food and drinks apart from water in hotels, restaurants and cafes from 1st September 2011. Therefore, within 18 months, the rates for restaurants were increased from 9% to 23%. Due to its negative effect, this rate was again reduced to 13% on 1st August 2013. Therefore these measures increased the prices of the exports of the second most important export industry and were in no way neutral. The higher prices for restaurants, cafes and hotels had mainly devastating effects in a very price-sensitive low-price sector (one-star to three-star hotels). They contributed decisively to the severe crisis in this sector.

- Due to the increase in taxes and the fall in wages and government spending, the budget deficit for the current period has fallen. A primary surplus is coming closer. However, tax revenues will subsequently dwindle because the nominal incomes and sales which are subject to tax will collapse again. The fact that tax evasion and unreported employment has been encouraged instead of reduced by the combination of increased VAT, income tax and corporation tax is of importance for this effect. For many self-employed persons and companies there is no other way out because the majority of their clients cannot pay their bills. Companies are acting in this way so that they can accumulate a liquidity reserve because no more liquidity can be obtained from the banking system.

- Finally, this policy had a considerable effect on property prices and hence, through the backcoupling effect, on the availability of credit in turn. Because the number of property transactions and the average prices have fallen due to the imposed credit crunch, the revenues from property transactions have shrunk. This was compensated for with increases in taxes on property ownership or, in Greece’s case, even way overcompensated for. Their effect increases the downward pressure on property prices and therefore on the values of loan collateral. Therefore, the quite massive tax increases contribute indirectly to the systemic banking crisis and the credit crunch through loan defaults and the losses associated therewith.

The whole Troika approach lacked and lacks any coherent overall design. Greece’s deficient tax system, which is justly faulted by the country itself, has given way to a system for the reduction or permanent destruction of part of the tax base. The worst components are the VAT increases. They represent the greatest incentive for tax evasion and unreported work and also act as brakes on the exports of the tourism industry. When wage reductions were being implemented, it was thought that this would have only a partial effect on exports. The fact that Greece’s exports are not very sensitive to labour costs at all and that tax yields would collapse due to the drastic reduction in wages subject to tax and social security contributions was ignored. The foreign trade price shock and the interbank crisis led to the first economic collapse and cause the first phase of the credit crunch. Monetary policy led to a severe banking crisis and made the credit crunch permanent. Fiscal policy disabled the economy’s automatic stabilisers and thereby reinforced a downward spiral.

What is the result, what is the overall dynamic of the Greek tragedy? Greece has had a structural problem in the banking system and the money supply process for decades. The earnings of the most important export industry do not enter the domestic banking system or only do so to a very limited extent, but rather end up in offshore USD accounts abroad. In the past, under different currency regimes, this was a source of macroeconomic instability and remains so today. Since the introduction of the euro, the credit expansion, which accelerated from 2004, led to a dangerous financing of long-term loans through short-term interbank funds from abroad. The triggering events for the crisis were the oil shocks, the US financial crisis and the ECB’s restrictive monetary policy in the eurozone from 2008. These factors set off a preliminary credit crunch and a rapid and deep economic collapse in the periphery countries. For Greece in particular, the collapse in the freight rates of the shipping industry, the country’s most important export industry, is of outstanding significance. An external deflation in the export industry was thus set in train; one which has lasted till now. The prevailing opinion of the Troika’s experts is based on the exports and current account figures which for decades have been incorrectly calculated from a conceptual standpoint by the Greek authorities. The European Central Bank and the IMF are also partly responsible for this. So the real causes of the Greek crisis are erroneously represented by their representatives and a crisis therapy which is completely wrongly targeted from an economic policy standpoint has been imposed. The crisis was interpreted as a crisis of competitiveness and excessively high unit labour costs and an internal devaluation was seen as the cure.

Due to the Troika’s policy, the massive external deflation led to the addition of a massive internal deflation. Because wage costs are not so important in the capital- intensive growth areas of the export industry, there is no stimulating effect on exports. Quite the opposite: internal deflation resulted in a further escalation of the banking system’s bad loans. Furthermore, the extremely rapid increase in non-performing and bad loans aggravated the banking system’s solvency problem. The banks must quickly provide reserves for loans that are no longer being serviced after 90 days and even more so for loans which have gone bad due to bankruptcies. This constantly reduces the capital available for lending. The structural credit crunch and the liquidity panic were fuelled in this manner by constantly fresh equity losses – a vicious cycle.

In Greece, just like in the whole of Europe, real estate is the most important collateral for the lending process. It is mortgaged in household mortgage lending and in many corporate loans. Furthermore, in Greece, ships are very important in shipping loans. They constitute the collateral for the loans to shipowners. The fall in freight rates also led to a sharp drop in the resale values of newly constructed and already used ships. However, there is still a liquid and a global market.

Conversely, the real estate market is local, regional or national. Property can no longer be sold not least because there are no more mortgage loans. The whole credit mechanism has collapsed. Banks can no longer foreclose on security interests as they are sitting on a mountain of illiquid collateral and therefore no longer can or want to take on any more real estate risks.

What has been taking place in Greece before our eyes is described as debt deflation. After a phase of rapid credit expansion and high, but unstable growth dynamics, a cumulatively intensifying economic collapse occurs, associated with a severe deflation. The preceding credit expansion is usually accompanied by low interest rates and a defective deregulation of the financial sector, which renders it fragile. After a high interest rates phase and the classical “Minsky moment”, the interbank panics of 2008 and 2010, an economic downturn begins. The prices for produced goods and services and nominal incomes start to fall as well as those of the important assets and collateral for the lending process, which is described as “collateral debt deflation”. Conversely, the private non-financial sector’s existing debt to the banking system and to the state and the social welfare system is nominal and remains unchanged. Hence, indebtedness constantly rises in real terms and meteorically. Due to the banks’ thinned equity capital cover and withdrawal panics with respect to bank deposits, the banks’ nominal lending rates also remain relatively high. Interest rates on debt service also increase in real terms and render debt unsustainable. The falls in the prices of assets which serve as banks’ collateral for lending and withdrawal panics lead to a financial accelerant which results in a cumulatively intensifying economic collapse.

Greece is going through a process similar to the Great Depression of the 1930s in the United States. For the U.S., Friedman and Schwartz (1963) identified the passivity of the Federal Reserve in the preliminary stages and during the banking panic as the major cause of the change from an initially sharp recession into a severe economic depression. They identified the resistance to the use of discount windows and the refusal to aggressively purchase government bonds as being responsible for these panics. In several publications in the 1980s and 1990s, Bernanke and various co-authors brought out the decisive role of the credit channels in this process. The drop in the value of credit collateral led to a progressive credit crunch in the whole banking system. In Greece’s case, it is not a passive and cautious monetary policy but rather an active one, which has temporarily destroyed the banking system’s equity, only belatedly and incompletely restored, and thus caused a long phase of a systemic banking crisis. Then the creditor countries and the ECB operated with the threat “Liquidity only for reforms” and thus contributed and are contributing actively to the withdrawal panic. This is how monetary policy manoeuvred the country into an economic collapse. On the other hand, the Greek central bank and the ECB up to June 27th 2015 aggressively resisted deposit withdrawals and thus prevented an immediate bank run. Therefore what has befallen Greece is a debt deflation of specific type, mainly expressing itself in a credit crunch and progressive liquidity crisis. It has for long been contained by very large liquidity injections from the central bank and indirectly the ECB. And as opposed to the 1930s it is not just the private sector debt against banks, but also against government which

What has been thus caused in Greece is unfortunately not a reform program for the improvement of competitiveness, but rather a destruction of a whole economy related to monetary, fiscal and structural policy. Naturally there are sensible reform elements in the Troika’s agenda like the debureaucratisation and the build-up of an effective tax administration, for example. However this is absolutely secondary in relation to what is happening in relation to demand policy. A severe deflation in foreign trade and a historic one-off destruction of the banking system’s whole equity with an ensuing unprecedented liquidity crisis and credit crunch and a fiscal policy with the elimination of all buffers add up and mutually amplify each other. The public debt crisis is only one manifestation of the liquidity crisis and it is not the primary driver.

(This part of the article has been written long before events of 27th of June during the month of April. I leave it unchanged and will add an update at the end of the economic policy scope and priorities)

What should be done? One school of thought, represented prominently by Hans-Werner Sinn in Germany, supports Greece’s exit from the eurozone in order to reduce unit labour costs and improve the country’s competitiveness in the export market. Such voices are also heard in Greece itself, even within the Syriza party. However, the historic experience with devaluations in Greece is miserable. The country did precisely this from 1982 onwards. Previously, the central bank de facto pegged the dollar exchange rate (until 1975) or devalued within a narrow band (1975 to 1982). The massive devaluation of the drachma from January 1983 onwards strategically uncoupled the USD accounts of shipping companies and the domestic banking system and completely barricaded the domestic banking system for years. This was accompanied by tightened credit and external capital controls. The inflow from shipowners’ remittances from abroad increased steeply in the postwar period up to and including 1981. On the other hand, from 1982 onwards until the introduction of the euro, this inflow stagnated although the shipping companies flying flags of convenience expanded strongly from 1986 onwards. The main point is that merchant shipping is an almost completely dollar-denominated sector. All earnings and the majority of expenditure are made in US dollars. For this reason, an exit from the euro would do nothing for the competitiveness of the most important export industry. Quite the contrary – it would probably lead to the physical abandonment of Greece as an operational centre. Shipowners, their management personnel and technical specialists would relocate to London, New York or Geneva and deprive Greece of its most important export industry. The operational preparations for this have been ongoing for years. The reason would be that they could only obtain loans and additional services such as insurance, payments or hedging through the Baltic Exchange for their highly capital-intensive sector in these financial centres. This has been ruled out in Greece for years or rather decades. The Greek fleet would not only be “invisible” or “missing” in the balance of payments statistics, but rather would have irreversibly disappeared in reality.

The tourism sector, the country’s second most important export industry, would in no way be impacted positively by an exit from the euro, the return to the drachma and a massive devaluation. Admittedly export demand would increase massively after a long transitional period of instability. However, there are tight limitations on a purely demand-driven export boom. Tourism in Greece is mainly seasonal tourism. Everything is concentrated on the four to five summer months. Capacity utilisation in this time period is also already high and achieves 80 – 90%. The analysis of hotel capacity and the overnight stay figures since the middle of the 1970s in the background text impressively shows that the supply effects of the currency regime are more important. Hotel capacity was built up when the currency was stable, interest rates were low and credit was available. This was the case in the 1970s, from 1995 in the higher added-value four-star segment and from 2002 onwards especially in the five-star segment. It is only in these two segments, especially in the five-star segments, that there is further growth potential. In this regard, capacity expansions can only be achieved by new construction or by comprehensive modernisation/renovation/expansion. Both require very high capital investment which cannot be obtained from the hotels’ ongoing operation. Borrowing is indispensable. This differentiates the construction of four - and five-star hotels from the traditional family hotels of lower classification. This is not possible with a devalued drachma and interest rates with high risk premia. The position is exactly the reverse of the popular conception that devaluation would have a positive effect. The growth potential of the tourism sector lies in the five-star and hotel sector and at most the four-star sector. Both these sectors are very capital-intensive. Investments in this sector are heavily dependent on very low and stable interest rates. This growth sector will only have an opportunity to fulfil its potential if Greece remains in the euro and there is a return to very low interest rates and normal credit availability.

The school of thought which holds that unit labour costs should be the major focus of attention – and by so doing does not understand them – is not only based on Greece’s incorrectly calculated official current account and gross domestic product figures. It is also based on a fundamentally incorrect concept of the balance of payments, which the current account elevates as a partial balance sheet and makes an absolute standard for competitiveness. Global terms of trade in foreign trade, which are completely dominant in Greece’s case and extensively so in other periphery countries, are hidden. The effect of the oil price shocks as by far the greatest driver of the trade and the current account balance is thus ignored. The growth in freight rates as the most important engine of exports of services is not taken into consideration at all. Secondly, all the refinements and vagaries of the measurement of exports and imports, especially in the services sector, are absolutely ignored. Thirdly, the effect of variable interest rates on the income balance is not taken into effect. The rise in recorded current account deficits in the periphery countries between 2004 and 2010 is, in addition to the oil effect, attributable to the increased interest costs on external debt and not to any competitive effects. This applies not only to Greece, but also to all periphery countries. Fourthly, the role of direct investments and purchases of second homes in the tourism industry is hidden. Given the economic structure of Greece and the other periphery countries, the balances of the recorded current account are not a suitable measure of a country’s competitiveness. They are a statistical construct and are completely irrelevant and extremely misleading in their concretely recorded form. Greece’s competitiveness as an economy improved massively during the boom of the 2000s, in contrast to what the recorded current account suggested. And it has since then fallen, while the official current account indicates an improvement. The exact same thing also applies to the other periphery countries to a modified extent.

This school of thought has never analysed the shipping industry or the tourism industry’s business models and does not understand the positive effect of the introduction of the euro on these two leading industries which are both very capital-intensive. An exit from the euro would combine a severe and irreversible collapse in shipping industry exports, an adjustment recession in the tourism industry with a subsequent long stagnation and a collapse of the domestic economy. This would mean not only a partial debt write-off for the creditor countries, but a complete and irreversible loss. With this, credit country taxpayers, not only Germany’s, but also Italy’s, Spain’s, France’s or those of the small eurozone countries would suffer an irreversible loss of about 3-4% of their gross domestic product from the historically unexampled bailout action and within a few years. This experience would be politically traumatic. It would obstruct all steps in the direction of Europe’s political integration for years or decades and initiate a process of a return to the nation state and the disintegration of the euro. Europe could disintegrate politically, economically and socially with unforeseeable consequences for the standard of living and the political development in the individual member states.

The institutions’ or Troika representatives and the newly elected Greek government had lengthy and completely awkard discussions. However, what has been discussed completely overlooked the heart of the country’s dramatic economic problem. It should not have been a matter of making fresh loans again in order to enable the servicing of government debt for a couple of months. Especially not at all if this is to be linked to “reforms” of the existing type. The demands by the Troika revealed a catastrophic misperception of the Greek crisis.

In Greece, the banking system is on the brink of collapse and the country on the brink of the worst depression ever in economic history. According to the official figures of the Bank of Greece, at the end of 2013, the banks had a non-performing loans ratio of 31.2%. The European Commission sets the ratio for this time at 33% and the IMF fixes it at 40%. Meanwhile, according to the evidence, it has increased. No more official data have been published since then but evaluations can be made on the basis of the data from the four large banks. This ratio increased further in 2014, and it obviously increased at an accelerated rate again in 2015. Added to this is the massively increased outflow of deposits which has massively intensified the banks’ assets and liabilities management problems or indeed rendered them insoluble. What characterises the banking systems of the periphery countries, and that of Greece’s first and foremost, is a severe solvency and financing problem, not just a liquidity problem. These fundamental problems of the banking sectors require three solutions; first, a rapid boosting of equity, then a clean-up of loan portfolios and finally a rebuilding of the banking system’s deposit base.

The danger of a bank panic can only be defused by an immediate injection of equity capital. At least 40 to 50 billion euros will be required for this in Greece. Under no circumstances should these funds be handed over to the banks in the same way as the contribution for which there is no hope of a return. The banks must either be immediately nationalised or have their capital holes plugged with a compulsory recapitalisation by means of the taking of equity stakes through the bailout fund, whereupon the anyway only fictive share value of the existing shareholders would be diluted or devalued. However, this would only be a first step. In parallel with this, the banks’ bad loans must be transferred to a “bad bank”. This must be properly established from a business model standpoint. This did not happen in Ireland (NAMA) or in Spain (SAREB), with serious consequences. This will also cost money at first, but can be funded partly or in the long term by sales. This is the only way to restore the public’s confidence in the continual solidity of the banking system. At the same time, withholding taxes on interest yields on domestic bank deposits must be abolished, but maintained for foreign bank deposits. All companies with external activities must be pressured into reporting their existing inventories to the central bank. Legislation must be prepared together with leading representatives of the shipowners so that they will transfer the greater part of their cash inventory from accounts abroad to banks in Greece. This will not happen without pressure (tax fraud in the past), but also not without guarantees and indeed, not only from the Greek government, but from the ECB or the bailout fund. Anything else is wishful thinking. This is the only way that the banking system can regain a solid deposit base. These guarantees would be justified by the fact that in 2011 the Greek banking system’s equity and risk capital was almost destroyed by the Troika with a stroke of the pen and is being constantly eroded since then due to negligent blackmailing to rebuild equity capital in tranches.

Such a capital inflow would cost money at first. If the exercise is properly structured, in contrast to the poorly prepared 2011 refinancing, then this additional capital injection can be recovered several times over within a few years during a future privatisation when the banks’ economic value increases. However, there must be an accompanying move towards reality. Something must definitely be done about Greece’s extremely serious statistics problem. This is the only way to prevent the figures constantly sending wrong signals and leading to an inappropriate policy.

Actually, in Greece, there is a break needed with the Troika’s policy with respect to fiscal policy. Admittedly, a fiscal consolidation is required, but certainly not up to now and especially in a quite different location. The consequence of the existing policy – a drop in exports, combined with an imposed credit collapse and a restrictive fiscal policy in the domestic economy – is a rapid rise in the banking system’s bad loans. It makes absolutely no sense to continue with a restrictive fiscal policy in the current form. The finances of private households and company are so destroyed that a further drop in demand leads to a further increasing level of bad loans in the banks and to the inability of households and companies to pay tax. Therefore, a write-off of public debt is less important than a write-off for portions of the debt of over- indebted private households and companies. Public debt only requires a refinancing with lower interest rates. If anything is to be brought to Greece quickly, ins substantial amounts and without undesired economic effects, it should come from the offshore accounts abroad. Not with new taxes, however, but rather only for past tax evasion. And in this respect, the Greek government will rely heavily on the US, the UK, Switzerland and Eurozone partners in order to be able to implement something like this. What Greece can certainly do is to design a tax amnesty cleverly so that it will yield considerable proceeds. Lengthy procedures are never as effective as a custom-made and quickly implemented tax amnesty.

(Update after the weekend of 27 of June)

The mother of all bank panics did happen in Greece, with catastrophic consequences for the country and for Europe to come. A bank panic of this magnitude itself is a major macroeconomic shock or disaster. It will profoundly change the psychology and behaviour of economic agents in Greece immediately and for a long time. Bank lending will now completely collapse and the associated liquidity drought will exert an immediate and powerful effect on companies. Illiquidity will drive even solvent companies into risks of bankruptcies quickly, setting up a chain or cascade of bankruptcies even among the best capitalized corporations. Investment and consumer demand will contract to an absolute minimum or come to a standstill. Imports will dry up, and even exports will start to suffer. The public sector will stop to pay bills. Existing bills in the private sector won’t be settled anymore. New deliveries only will be done against prepayments. A core meltdown is in the making. What makes it worse, is that it happens after a sharp economic contraction lasting for six years. The country is in a situation just comparable to the United States or Germany in the 1930s. Buffers and liquidity reserves of most actors already have dwindled or are gone. There is no way to escape the fact, that the country will suffer now the worst depression in modern economic history. After seven years of uninterrupted depression, a full-blown banking crisis is the ultimate catastrophe to arrive.

To avert the worst a huge immediate widening of ELA facilities is required. Liquidity is the top priority in such as situation. In a comment, Martin Hellwig has stressed the irrelevance of the argument, that only solvent banks should be supported by liquidity. This refers to a monetary system, where money was backed by gold. In a pure paper money as today, it is meaningless. The liquidity drought in itself creates the insolvency of the banking system. As a second pillar to stop the banking panic, a deposit insurance guarantee by international creditors for the EUR 100’000 at a minimum, but better for the whole deposits is needed. Further, an injection of equity capital into the banking system should be added. The losses given default in a situation of such a banking crisis will be a multiple of the worst case calculations underlying capital requirements. In the text a sum of 40-50 bn euro was mentioned. After the shock we are talking of possibly more. The bank’s should be fully nationalized, but controlled by trustworthy outside agents. The Greece government, though its behaviour is understandable and reveals despair as background, is not to be considered trustworthy at this point in time. The associated step is to immediately remove the non-performing assets from the banks into a single large ‘Bad bank’. Otherwise the trust will not come back. With increased ELA-facilities the liability side will have to be initially stabilized. The withholding on bank deposits should immediately removed for domestic bank deposits. Finally, in the medium term, the tonnage tax system must be tweaked in the sense, that the Greek reeders may keep their existing tax privileges, but just in case they hold liquidity to a large degree in Greece.

As a result of the bank panic and the depression to come, Greece budget deficits will inevitably increase, and potentially forcefully. Public debt will not have to be cut, but just rescheduled in order to avoid interest and principal payments in the three to five years to come. The revenue from future bank privatisations should be used to reduce the debt. And finally, with the private sector in full contraction, there is no way to avoid a large scale spending program in Greece. It should focus on infrastructure for the main export industries, tourism and shipping. To privatize the port of Piraeus and sell the port to Chinese future competitors seems to be an odd conclusion. Right now I cannot even imagine that such a proposal will succeed in the Eurozone. But it is the only way to avert a full scale collapse that is made up by the private sector demand contraction.

With respect to immediate revenue generation, an intelligently designed tax amnesty is needed. At the core is that shipowners have to disclose all their foreign mostly offshore accounts and transactions of the last 20, better 30 years at a minimum. All of them, for every single ship, holding company and private account. That directly will yield the withholding tax. Furthermore, it will make transparent all the offshore transactions that were executed to avoid taxation in the domestic economy. It will reveal the accounts of counterparties and lead to those offshore accounts. What should be imposed then, is not just all the tax revenue that the Greek state lost plus interest on it. A harsh punitive tax should be imposed, if shipowners try to cheat and continue to hide offshore accounts or try to flee outside the country. For shipowners that are not able to pay, a payment schedule should be worked out, that allows them to stay in business. The tax may be reduced, if tax evaders indicate tax avoidance with other parties and name the accounts and transactions. The second reduction should be taken if the tax evaders pay taxes due immediately. A third reduction should occur, if part of the taxes are used to invest in activity in Greece in a short period of time where taxes and social security contributions are paid. What is valid for the reeders, should be applied to other sectors of the economy as well. Offshore accounts have to be immediately made transparent to tax offices for long periods of time, 20 to 30 years back. If they are hidden, harsh punitive taxes should be additionally raised. The same type of tax reduction should be applied as in the case of shipowners.

To succeed Greece needs the support of the United States, the UK, Switzerland and Euro governments. These governments must deliver to a common Troika / Greece committee a full list of all accounts and banking transactions of identified Greek offshore accounts with high priority. For shipowners and other companies and private individuals with offshore accounts it will pay off to fully disclose their accounts and transactions. By such behaviour, they can contribute to avoid a catastrophic collapse of Greece, where their domestic assets will lose all or almost all of their value.

For the domestic informal economy, similar type of expertise has to be built up. It is key to invest into tax office infrastructure and training of skilled employees. However, this will be a longer term project. The priority short-term should be on offshore accounts. There huge sums are hidden that are not used productively in the Greek ecoomy right now. The Greek government will present a simplified tax code in due time to reduce complexity and to improve the tax collection.

If policymakers in the Eurozone fail to rethink their approach quickly, it will have serious repercussions for them as well. In this case European creditors will lose everything and probably once and forever. Same for the IMF. The new currency will devalue initially in a big way. What Greece must avoid, is a policy of the sliding Drachma like in the 1980s. The new approach should be to peg the dollar after initial decline, and after a period of stability to actively manage the currency. It will require substantial financial support from outside to achieve stabilization. One of the first measures will have to be to look in detail at the procedures of the central bank. The Greek central bank is a real risk for the country with its history of inability to design a balance of payments and to achieve a stable financial system. In both cases the truth about the shameful fact that Greece is a big exporter should be presented to internal and international public. To assist a massacre of its own economy without correcting its course was a huge mistake. The other institutions to be blamed are the IMF and to a lesser extent the ECB.

As far as other measures are involved a specific program should be developed over a period of several months. At this point in time no further restrictive policy measures should be targeted. A new program has to be tailor-made to the grave situation.

 

Inhalt wird nicht angezeigt, da Sie keine externen Cookies akzeptiert haben. Ändern..


Mehr zum Thema:  
Europa >

DWN
Finanzen
Finanzen Smallcap-Aktien: Lohnt sich ein Investment?
29.03.2024

Nebenwerte sind derzeit relativ gering bewertet und könnten von Zinssenkungen profitieren. Macht ein Einstieg Sinn für risikobereite...

DWN
Finanzen
Finanzen Bundesbank: Erholung der deutschen Wirtschaft verzögert sich
29.03.2024

Europas größte Volkswirtschaft kommt nicht richtig in Fahrt. Die Aussichten für die nächsten Monate sind nach Experteneinschätzung...

DWN
Unternehmen
Unternehmen Neue Reiseziele: So manche Überraschung im Sommerflugplan
29.03.2024

Ab Ostern tritt an den deutschen Flughäfen der neue Sommerflugplan in Kraft. Die Deutschen Wirtschaftsnachrichten haben für Sie als Leser...

DWN
Politik
Politik Vor 20 Jahren: Größte Erweiterung der Nato - eine kritische Betrachtung
29.03.2024

Am 29. März 2004 traten sieben osteuropäische Länder der Nato bei. Nicht bei allen sorgte dies für Begeisterung. Auch der russische...

DWN
Technologie
Technologie Viele Studierende rechnen mit KI-Erleichterungen im Joballtag
29.03.2024

Vielen Menschen macht Künstliche Intelligenz Angst, zum Beispiel weil KI Arbeitsplätze bedrohen könnte. In einer Umfrage stellte sich...

DWN
Politik
Politik Verfassungsgericht stärken: Mehrheit der Parteien auf dem Weg zur Einigung?
28.03.2024

Das Verfassungsgericht soll gestärkt werden - gegen etwaige knappe Mehrheiten im Bundestag in aller Zukunft. Eine Einigung zeichnet sich...

DWN
Weltwirtschaft
Weltwirtschaft Deutschlands maue Wirtschaftslage verhärtet sich
28.03.2024

Das DIW-Konjunkturbarometer enttäuscht und signalisiert dauerhafte wirtschaftliche Stagnation. Unterdessen blieb der erhoffte...

DWN
Politik
Politik Corona-Aufarbeitung: Lauterbach will RKI-Protokolle weitgehend entschwärzen
28.03.2024

Gesundheitsminister Karl Lauterbach hat angekündigt, dass einige der geschwärzten Stellen in den Corona-Protokollen des RKI aus der...